Topic: finanzas públicas

American Spatial Development and the New Megalopolis

Armando Carbonell and Robert D. Yaro, Abril 1, 2005

This article is adapted from a policy roundtable report on national spatial development strategies prepared under the auspices of the Lincoln Institute, Regional Plan Association and the University of Pennsylvania School of Design. The roundtable was held in September 2004 at the Pocantico Conference Center of the Rockefeller Brothers Fund. The impetus for this project developed in the spring of 2004 in a graduate city planning studio directed by Robert Yaro and Jonathan Barnett, both Practice Professors in City and Regional Planning at Penn, and Visiting Professor Armando Carbonell. With funding support from the Ford Foundation’s Institute of International Education, additional input was provided by a distinguished team of European and American planning experts hosted by Professor Sir Peter Hall at the Institute of Community Studies in London, England.

European efforts to develop policies and investments for the entire continent and for regions that cross national boundaries have been organized under the umbrella of the European Spatial Development Perspective, a set of policy directives and strategies adopted by the European Union in 1999 (Faludi 2002). Over the past generation the EU has initiated a large-scale approach to planning for metropolitan growth, mobility, environmental protection and economic development. Europeans use the umbrella term “spatial planning” to describe this process, involving plans that span regional and national borders and encompass new “network cities” spread out over hundreds of kilometers (see Figure 1). The EU is also mobilizing public and private resources at the continental scale, with bold plans and investments designed to integrate the economies of and reduce the economic disparities between member states and regions, and to increase the competitiveness of the continent in global markets.

By contrast, the United States has no strategy to anticipate and manage comparable concerns, even though the U.S. population is expected to grow another 40 percent by 2050. How can this growth be accommodated in metropolitan regions that are already choking on congestion and approaching build-out under current trends and policies? How can we improve the competitiveness and livability of our own emerging constellation of network cities? How can the U.S. reduce the growing disparities in wealth and population among fast-growing coastal regions, vast interior rural areas and declining industrial cities? How can the U.S. promote regional strategies designed to address these concerns?

Two important precedents have shaped this analysis of America’s spatial development. The national development and conservation strategies prepared by President Thomas Jefferson in 1807 and President Theodore Roosevelt in 1907 stimulated the major infrastructure, conservation and regional economic development strategies that powered America’s economic growth in its first two centuries. Other major strategies and investments promoted in the administrations of Presidents Lincoln, Franklin Roosevelt and Eisenhower also had a profound impact on the nation’s growth. Some examples are the Morrill Act land grant university system, the Homestead Act, and creation of the national rail and interstate highway systems.

Economic, Demographic and Spatial Trends

Rapid population growth

The U.S. Census Bureau forecasts that the nation’s population will grow by 40 percent to 430 million by 2050, whereas most European countries are expected to lose significant numbers of residents, due to declining birth rates and limited immigration. This means we must build half again as much housing and as much commercial and retail space and the infrastructure needed to support these activities in the next half century as we have in the past two centuries.

The study of historical settlement patterns sheds light on current and future patterns. While early settlers clung primarily to the coasts and in compact urban regions, the inventions of rail transportation and later the automobile forever changed settlement patterns and allowed people to set up homes in the interior of the country and in highly decentralized metropolitan areas. Fast-growing Sunbelt states, such as Texas, California and Florida, are expected to see sustained rapid population growth, spurred by the trend of immigrant populations settling in those and surrounding states.

While most central cities will continue to grow at a moderate pace, many metropolitan regions around these urban cores are expected to experience remarkable development. As the city of Philadelphia continues to lose population, for example, its adjacent suburbs and areas further outside the city continue to grow. In general, however, the number of people living in urbanized areas as opposed to rural areas is projected to continue rising, signaling an increase in the amount of urbanized land in the coming decades.

The building out of suburban America

Since 1970 the vast majority of the nation’s economic and population growth has occurred in 30 large metropolitan regions, mostly in their sprawling outer rings. While some cities and inner-ring suburbs are now experiencing infill development and renewed population growth, many others are approaching “build-out,” which increases traffic congestion and commuting times, contributes to loss of farmland, and creates conflicts between new development and green infrastructure, such as public water supplies and wildlife habitat.

In less than three centuries, 46 million acres of America’s virgin landscape have been converted to urban uses. In the next 25 years that number will more than double to 112 million acres. If current growth and land consumption rates continue, another 100 million acres will be urbanized by 2050, at a rate seven times faster than the population will grow.

Uneven and inequitable growth patterns

While most population and economic growth has been in large metropolitan regions, other areas of the country have experienced losses. Large rural regions where resource-based economies or groundwater reserves are in permanent decline are left without the means to support even basic services. A number of large urban centers and second-tier cities also have experienced decades of decline. For example, Philadelphia, Baltimore, Pittsburgh, Cleveland, Detroit, St. Louis and New Orleans have lost a third or more of their populations since 1960. Even in cities where the outer-ring suburbs have grown, many inner cities and inner-ring suburbs have lost residents, tax base and economic activity, and poverty has become highly concentrated. Many of these places have high concentrations of African-Americans, Native Americans, Latinos and poor whites who will be increasingly disadvantaged as economic opportunities in these regions decline.

In contrast with the U.S., the European Union for decades has invested vast sums to promote development and redevelopment of comparable bypassed areas. These investments have produced dramatic results in revitalizing the economies of Ireland, Spain, Portugal and Greece, and formerly depressed cities and regions in Europe’s periphery. Similar strategic investments in America’s disadvantaged cities and regions could produce comparable results.

Limited infrastructure capacity

Metropolitan infrastructure of all kinds, most of it built in the last half of the twentieth century, will reach its capacity limits in the first decades of the twenty-first century. Unless new capacity is created in roads, rails, airports, seaports and other systems, the nation’s economic potential will be artificially limited. Federal transportation investments over the past decade have been largely focused on maintaining the existing infrastructure, not on expanding the capacity of these systems.

Over the last 50 years, Americans have become increasingly mobile. The increase in miles traveled per person has been most pronounced in car and aircraft travel, creating new challenges to keep various types of transportation corridors congestion-free. At the same time, congestion poses a serious threat to manufacturing and freight sectors of the economy. Experts believe that by 2020 there will be nearly a doubling of trucks on the roadways over current numbers. Significant policy measures are needed to channel more resources into high-capacity transportation systems for both individual and commercial activity.

Emergence of megalopolis

In 1961 French geographer Jean Gottman described the Boston–Washington Megalopolis. Between now and 2050, more than half of the nation’s population growth, and perhaps as much as two-thirds of its economic growth, will occur in this and seven other emerging megalopolitan regions whose extended networks of metropolitan centers are linked by interstate highway and rail corridors. Similar networks of cities in Europe and Asia are now seen as the new competitive units in the global economy. Major public and private investments are being made in high-speed rail, broadband communications and other infrastructure to strengthen transportation and economic synergies among their component centers.

The New Megalopolis

The new megalopolis is a model for cooperation among the cities and regions in the U.S. that are growing together and creating diseconomies in congested transportation networks, which in turn affect the economic vitality and quality of life of these regions. This model is based on the idea that if the cities in these colliding regions work together they can create a new urban form that will increase economic opportunity and global competitiveness for each individual city and for the nation as a whole.

These component metropolitan areas will have to cooperate in the formation of a structure that takes advantage of the complementary roles of each area while addressing common concerns in the areas of transportation, economic development, environmental protection, and equity. The new megalopolis model will contribute to improving social and economic cohesion along with a better territorial balance, and will support more sustainable development by emphasizing collaboration on important policy issues, infrastructure investments and instruments for facilitating economic growth and job creation.

To facilitate the development of megalopolitan areas, the U.S. could focus on creating a truly intermodal network linking rail, highway and air transportation. Such connections would relieve congested airports and provide greater options for freight movement. The resulting transportation flexibility would be less vulnerable to terrorist attacks and disaster. Furthermore, regional infrastructure and development focused around rail stations would shape and redirect urban growth in more efficient, less sprawling patterns.

Our current direction is building a country whose competitiveness is threatened by inefficient urban forms and declining rural communities. The new megalopolis concept points us in a different direction, one in which urban areas and their surrounding regions work together on a larger scale to address common concerns and share their complementary strengths. This new model would produce an America that is environmentally sustainable, socially equitable, and competitive in an increasingly global economy.

Six distinctive regions can be identified based on common history, geographic location and topography: the Northeast, Mid-Atlantic, South, Midwest, Southwest and West. Most of the nation’s rapid population growth, and an even larger share of its economic expansion, is expected to occur in eight emerging metropolitan areas spread over thousands of square miles and located in every one of these regions (see Figure 2). These megalopolitan areas are becoming America’s economic engines: centers of technological and cultural innovation where the vast majority of immigrants who are driving population and economic growth will assimilate into the economic and social mainstream.

In Europe and Asia similar network cities are already being seen as the new competitive units in the global economy. The European Union and national governments in Europe, China and Japan are investing hundreds of billions of dollars in new intermodal transportation and communication links and other infrastructure to underpin the capacity, efficiency and livability of these regions. In all of these places, new high-speed rail networks are integrating the economies of formerly isolated regions.

Toward an American Spatial Development Perspective

An American Spatial Development Perspective (ASDP) could encompass long-range strategies to achieve five broad national goals.

  1. Facilitate the emergence of eight new megalopolitan areas that can compete with similar emerging networks of cities in Europe and Asia.
  2. Create capacity for growth and improved global competitiveness in the nation’s transportation and other infrastructure systems.
  3. Provide resiliency, redundancy and capacity in the nation’s infrastructure to respond to national security needs.
  4. Revitalize bypassed urban and rural regions.
  5. Protect and reclaim important nationally significant natural resource systems and promote less land-consuming patterns of growth.

The federal government could play a crucial role in this process, through collaborations with existing and emerging “bottom-up” networks of interconnected regional strategies, encompassing each of the emerging megalopoli. Ideally, the federal government would help coordinate and “incentivize” these planning efforts, but rely on local and regional initiatives to drive each region’s own strategies.

The federal government could also lead in coordinating infrastructure planning and investments for national and regional intermodal, high-speed transportation networks, as it did in promoting creation of the national rail and interstate highway systems. These investments would be made through partnerships between federal, state and regional government, and private investors. User fees, tolls and fares would cover a substantial portion of the cost of developing and managing these systems.

Regional strategies could also promote investments in major higher education and research institutions needed to maintain the nation’s competitive advantage in technology and create a lifelong learning system to help skilled workers adapt to economic change. This broad approach could also identify the important natural resource systems that sustain public water supplies, biological resources, sense of place and recreational opportunities. Future growth could be designed to reuse formerly used sites and to reclaim and restore impaired landscapes and natural resource systems.

Plans for these infrastructure systems should be closely coordinated with strategies for smaller-scale urban and regional development, to ensure that future development patterns support, and are supported by, these infrastructure investments. Federal and state governments could invest in demonstration projects to test innovative transportation, land use, environmental and other strategies.

Building and Financing the ASDP

The proposed new infrastructure systems and urban development outlined in this article could cost trillions of dollars, much of which could be financed through user fees and public-private partnerships. It should also be possible to employ modest payroll or other taxes to finance some of these investments, which would generate trillions of dollars of new economic capacity for the whole nation. The expected doubling of the national economy by 2050 would expand the gross domestic product by more than $14 trillion (in constant dollars). Redirecting even a small share of the growth of tax revenues in these strategic investments could secure the nation’s economic future.

For over a hundred years, the U.S. has financed major infrastructure projects through a “top-down” system, with major funding from the federal government complemented by state resources. Based on general public agreement of national priorities, this model financed several generations of growth and paid for one of the world’s great infrastructure systems. However, this approach is now being challenged as the needs of maintaining our aging infrastructure systems outpace federal and state funding, to say nothing of new capacity expansion. Today we witness a debate between “donor” and “donee” states over the fairness of federal transportation funds, even as the total amount of federal dollars falls far short of estimated needs. As a result, we find ourselves increasingly starved for capital for infrastructure systems.

To provide more funding for system maintenance and expansion, metropolitan regions are looking to new and innovative financing systems. Public authorities use their tax-free status to attract private dollars through bond issuances, sales and lease-back arrangements. New user fees, such as congestion pricing or high-occupancy-vehicle lanes on toll roads, link charges to those who benefit the most from new investments, creating new revenue streams. And value capture models, such as tax increment financing, allow increases in land values to finance infrastructure investments.

The federal government is advancing instruments such as TIFIA, the Transportation Infrastructure Innovation Act, to stimulate the development of these projects. However, megalopolitan areas have a critical role to play in this emerging system. They provide a vital link between state and federal government and local jurisdictions, which in many cases have the last word over land use decisions. These regional areas transcend political boundaries and capture the true economic and social geography of their communities. And they have the size, capacity and expertise to undertake complex planning strategies.

Armando Carbonell is senior fellow and co-chair of the Lincoln Institute’s Department of Planning and Development. Robert D. Yaro is president of the Regional Plan Association in New York City.

References

Faludi, Andreas, ed. 2002. European spatial planning. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and Regional Plan Association. 2004. Toward an American spatial development perspective. Policy Roundtable Report. September.

University of Pennsylvania School of Design. 2004. Planning for America in a global economy: 2004–2005. City Planning Studio Report. Spring.

Faculty Profile

Petra Todorovich
Octubre 1, 2009

Faculty Profile: Petra Todorovich

Cities and Infrastructure

A Rough Road Ahead
Gregory K. Ingram and Anthony Flint, Julio 1, 2011

American cities have promising long-term prospects as hubs of innovation and growth, with expansion in technology and health sciences beginning to offset the decades-long erosion of manufacturing. Cities also remain places of vitality, offering urban design, density, and trans-port options that attract residents of all ages and backgrounds. In fact, nine of the ten most populous U.S. cities gained population over the last decade, according to the 2010 U.S. Census.

Yet the short-term prospects for cities are fraught with challenges. The recent sharp decline in tax revenues, caused by the 2008 housing market collapse and related financial crisis and economic slowdown, has made it extraordinarily difficult for state and local governments to maintain basic services, let alone plan for investments in infrastructure. Federal funds from the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) helped local governments offset revenue declines in the past three years, but ARRA funds are no longer available for the coming fiscal year (a transition now termed “the cliff”), leaving local officials to confront the full force of revenue shortfalls.

The 2011 Journalists Forum on Land and the Built Environment: The Next City brought scholars, practitioners, and political leaders together with print and broadcast journalists to explore the theme of infrastructure for cities in the context of the ongoing economic recovery. This program is an annual partnership of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, the Nieman Foundation for Journalism at Harvard University, and Harvard Graduate School of Design.

Two roles for infrastructure investments and related services permeated discussions at the Forum. First was the near-term role of investment in infrastructure as a fiscal stimulus aimed at turning around the economy and increasing employment. Second was the longer-term role that infrastructure plays in sustaining the transformation of municipal economies and increasing their competitiveness and livability in a globalized world.

Infrastructure and the Local Government Fiscal Crisis

The country’s need for fiscal stimulus to jump-start the economy in 2009 raised the prospect of massive infrastructure investments to help meet that need. However, the kinds of projects that could be launched quickly at the local level tended to be smaller-scale efforts, such as roadway repairs and facilities maintenance. More ambitious initiatives, such as intercity high-speed rail, failed to materialize due to spending and debt concerns and because much more design was needed before implementation could proceed.

Lawrence H. Summers, who recently returned to his professorship at Harvard after being director of the White House National Economic Council, defended the Obama administration’s stimulus plans, which he said were necessary to restore confidence in the financial system and keep the recession “out of the history books.” However, he said, “while local governments were able to use stimulus funds to cover revenue shortfalls, there were very few large shovel-ready projects.”

Moreover, the grim reality of fiscal stress is that cities cannot focus on large-scale, long-range infrastructure projects because they are struggling to cut spending and reform the delivery of local public services, noted Michael Cooper, reporter for The New York Times. Some examples of lost services include the Hawaii program that furloughs public school teachers every Friday through this school year; the San Diego boy who died choking on a gumball because a nearby fire station had been shuttered on a rotating basis; Colorado Springs’ decision to turn off a third of its streetlights each night and to auction off the police helicopter; and the California town that recalled its mayor because he revamped the city’s failing wooden pipes in its water system, but increased water fees to pay for it.

Many jurisdictions also have ongoing fiscal problems with the underfunding of pension funds and benefits. Some are worsening the problems simply by not making the required annual payments, a stopgap applied by Governor Chris Christie in New Jersey, among others. The municipal bond market faces tumult and some cities, like Harrisburg, Pennsylvania, are on the brink of bankruptcy. Fiscal deficits are growing because local governments have now expended the last of their

ARRA funds.

Adrian Fenty, former mayor of Washington, DC, said cities need to be run on a more business-like basis, moving to the politics of performance and away from the politics of patronage. Improvements are needed in both the efficiency of basic service delivery and the management of city finances. Because education is so important to the economic growth of cities, his administration gave priority to education reform—human infrastructure as well as physical infrastructure. During his term as mayor, his administration closed 20 percent of the schools and reduced administrative personnel by 50 percent. He also revamped teacher contracts, offering a merit pay system without tenure that 60 percent of the teachers opted to join.

Infrastructure Challenges: The Case of High-Speed Rail

President Barack Obama’s $53 billion high-speed rail initiative has brought the challenges of the local government fiscal crisis into sharp relief. Governors in Florida, Ohio, and Wisconsin returned the federal funding allocated to those states for intercity rail, claiming that their state and local governments could not possibly afford the resulting maintenance and operating costs, and questioning ridership projections. The high-speed rail project in California, though financed by a voter-approved bond issue, faces similar opposition because of financial burdens and local land use disputes.

Bruce Babbitt, former governor of Arizona and secretary of the U.S. Department of Interior, and a member of the Lincoln Institute board of directors, said the Obama administration’s campaign for high-speed intercity rail was a “political disaster,” and that the underlying vision needed a reassessment. He suggested that the Northeast Corridor should be the model, and that a revised plan should include a well-defined system of reliable financing—similar to the approach used to build the interstate highway system.

Paying for high-speed rail infrastructure will require a dedicated funding stream, perhaps from an increase in the gasoline tax in the states where the new rail lines would be located, and a system of value capture to engage private landowners who benefit from increases in property value as a result of such public works projects. “We don’t have the political courage to define our priorities,” Babbitt said. It will take a “national hammer” to address the nation’s infrastructure deficit without abdicating control to governors and states.

High-speed rail may live or die based on economic considerations. Petra Todorovich, executive director of America 2050, which has issued numerous analyses of high-speed rail’s potential, proposed a framework of 12 U.S. megaregions that represent collections of metropolitan areas where enhanced rail service offers the greatest potential for replacing automobile and short-haul airline travel. High-speed rail can deepen labor markets, increase agglomeration economies, and boost productivity by linking urban centers. Japan, France, and China are among the countries that have demonstrated how rail lines between major cities can foster economic synergies through the strategic location of high-speed rail stations and their connections to commuter rail and transit.

This economic payoff argument was seconded by Edward Rendell, former governor of Pennsylvania and mayor of Philadelphia, who is part of Building America’s Future, a campaign for investments in crumbling infrastructure nationwide. Rendell argued that the United States has been resting on its past investments, and that shoring up the nation’s decaying physical foundations is now an urgent priority. Without world-class infrastructure, the country will not be competitive in attracting private investment, sustaining rapid technological innovation and productivity growth, or maintaining the growth of good jobs domestically.

Infrastructure and the Future of Cities

As the recovery continues and economic growth returns, investments in new communication technology, green energy, smart urban systems, transport such as high-speed rail and mass transit, and other infrastructure will be needed to help cities fulfill their roles as the centers of innovation, culture, and productivity.

The vision of infrastructure combined with long-range planning is also a central theme in how cities can adapt to the inevitable impacts of climate change, including a possible one-meter sea level rise and associated storm surges, flooding, and increasing numbers of extreme weather events. Infrastructure in most coastal cities is so old that even a moderate storm event can do extensive damage, said Ed Blakely, public policy professor at the University of Sydney and former hurricane recovery czar in New Orleans.

Cities have been able to base their current plans on the relatively calm meteorological record of the last 200 years, but that calm is likely to erode with climate change, making much of the existing infrastructure inadequate or obsolete. Attention should not be focused on rebuilding after disasters like Hurricane Katrina, Blakely said, but on relocating, repositioning, and “future-proofing” for more resilient cities.

Infrastructure as an amenity that improves city livability is seen in New York’s High Line project, the conversion of an elevated freight line through the Meatpacking District and Greenwich Village. One of the architects on that project, Liz Diller, principal in Diller, Scofidio + Renfro, suggested that such retrofits can transform urban areas, provide a focal point for social and cultural events, and promote economic activity—though she cautioned that “architecture can’t really fix big problems.”

In spite of the current fiscal crisis, cities are expected to experience other changes that may aid their economic recovery. Among these are the fallout from the current housing crisis that is likely to spur demand for rental units and the demographic shift as the baby boom generation enters retirement age and begins to downsize housing choices.

Professor Arthur C. (Chris) Nelson, professor at the University of Utah, noted that both changes may generate more demand for urban lifestyles. For example, the current reduction in demand for owner-occupied, single-family houses at the metropolitan periphery is evident in the Intermountain West, Southwest, and South, where entire subdivisions are virtually empty. The percent of households owning homes has declined from a high of 69.2 percent in 2004 to 66.4 percent in 2011, fostering more demand for rental units that typically are located in more urbanized areas.

Demographic shifts are also related to changes in household composition. By 2030 single-person households will constitute one-third of the population, and only about one out of four households will include children, a decline from 45 percent with children in 1970 and 33 percent in 2000. These changes are likely to foster a significant adjustment in housing markets and values as aging baby boomers offer their suburban houses for sale and move to more urbanized locations with access to transit and walkable neighborhoods. At the same time, upcoming changes in mortgage markets and the reform of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac may make mortgage financing (and homeownership) more costly and cause younger families to choose renting over owning.

Cities as Engines of Growth

Investing in infrastructure to support metropolitan regions might have an additional rationale grounded in the surprising resilience of cities themselves. The ongoing urban resurgence is visible in the income growth of highly skilled professionals, the relatively modest housing price declines and even recent increases in several prospering cities, and a concentration of innovation in urban areas, said Harvard economics professor Edward Glaeser. “We could move anywhere that suits our biophilia,” he said. “Yet we keep flocking to cities.”

Urban population growth is highly correlated with average urban incomes, education levels, and the share of employment in small firms as cities continue to draw entrepreneurs and foster productivity. If incomes everywhere were like those in New York City, the national GDP would rise 43 percent, Glaeser said. Cities will also continue to be prized for their environmental value as places of density and transit, reflecting relatively lower per capita energy use and carbon emissions than suburban and rural areas. Glaeser argued against restrictive zoning and regulations that discourage greater density and leave older, low-rise urban neighborhoods “frozen in amber.” He also stressed that public education remains the most important investment that cities can and should make to enhance their continued economic growth and quality of life.

As both the national economy and local government revenues recover, a key priority will be to balance expenditures between current services and longer-term investments. Economic growth will make it easier to finance investments in infrastructure, but investments in infrastructure are needed to increase economic growth. The challenge is to find a politically feasible way of breaking into this virtuous circle.

About the Authors

Gregory K. Ingram is president and CEO of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Anthony Flint is fellow and director of public affairs at the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Informe del presidente

Regeneración de las ciudades industriales tradicionales de los Estados Unidos
Gregory K. Ingram, Julio 1, 2013

Durante las últimas décadas, la estructura de la economía de los EE.UU. ha cambiado, a medida que experimenta una continua reducción en el empleo fabril en general y un continuo crecimiento en el sector de los servicios, especialmente aquellos relacionados con los trabajadores capacitados. La distribución geográfica de la actividad también ha cambiado debido a que la población continúa moviéndose de las zonas noreste y medio oeste, en donde las estaciones son más marcadas, hacia las zonas sur y oeste, que son más cálidas. Finalmente, en las áreas metropolitanas, las poblaciones y el empleo se movieron de las ciudades a los suburbios, ya que los viajes en autobús y automóvil se han generalizado. Estas tres tendencias han provocado que muchas ciudades del noreste y oeste medio tengan ahora poblaciones mucho menores, economías más débiles, menos empleos fabriles y una incapacidad para compensar las oportunidades de empleo perdidas con las ganancias de sectores que se están expandiendo a nivel nacional. Estas son, hoy en día, las ciudades industriales históricas, que, con frecuencia, poseen una capacidad excesiva de infraestructura, una oferta de viviendas sin utilizar y una tensión fiscal relacionada con obligaciones asumidas en el pasado por sectores públicos que actualmente se encuentran muy disminuidos. En un reciente informe sobre enfoque en políticas de suelo del Instituto Lincoln, Regeneración de las ciudades tradicionales industriales de los Estados Unidos, sus autores, Alan Mallach y Lavea Brachman, analizan el desempeño de una muestra de estas áreas urbanas e identifican las medidas que han tomado las ciudades con más éxito para producir resultados más sólidos.

Aunque la decadencia de las ciudades industriales tradicionales posee causas comunes, el rendimiento económico de las mismas ha sido muy distinto en las últimas décadas, ya que muchas de estas ciudades han logrado resultados económicos, institucionales y fiscales más sólidos que otras. Todas las ciudades industriales antiguas poseen una serie de activos, tales como infraestructura, barrios, instituciones, poblaciones y actividades económicas en desarrollo. Las diferencias en su rendimiento, en forma comparativa, están relacionadas con la manera en que las políticas y el liderazgo municipal han sacado partido de los inventarios existentes de estos activos. En particular, las ciudades históricas tradicionales en vías de recuperación han construido y basado su expansión sobre instituciones preexistentes dedicadas a la investigación, la medicina, la salud y la educación. También han explotado el creciente interés por los barrios urbanos, donde resulta fácil ir caminando a las tiendas y a los restaurantes y donde las densidades residenciales son mayores que las de la mayoría de las comunidades suburbanas. Las ciudades en recuperación también, en general, han mantenido o atraído más residentes con mayores niveles de educación y han experimentado un crecimiento en las actividades relacionadas con el conocimiento.

Las ciudades industriales tradicionales que han visto cómo sus economías comienzan a transformarse y a crecer de nuevo no necesariamente experimentaron aumentos en sus poblaciones. La población de la mayoría de las ciudades tradicionales tuvo su pico de crecimiento a mediados del siglo XX y posteriormente descendió. Por ejemplo, Buffalo y St. Louis presentaron poblaciones más reducidas en el año 2000 que en 1900. A veces, la disminución de la población en estas ciudades se ve compensada por un crecimiento suburbano, por lo que las poblaciones metropolitanas no se reducen. Sin embargo, algunas ciudades tradicionales exitosas, tales como Pittsburgh, han experimentado leves reducciones de población incluso a nivel metropolitano. Cambiar la composición de las poblaciones de las ciudades y de su actividad económica es más importante para lograr el éxito que el crecimiento de la población por sí solo.

La exitosa recuperación de las ciudades industriales tradicionales normalmente no ha sido el resultado de megaproyectos enfocados en el redesarrollo, sino en el aumento de muchas medidas pequeñas que generan un gran impacto por acumulación, un enfoque que Mallach y Brachman han dado en llamar “crecimiento gradual estratégico”. En su investigación, los autores demuestran que las ciudades industriales tradicionales exitosas se han centrado en dicho enfoque de forma continua e incesante. Los elementos clave del crecimiento gradual estratégico requieren de la evolución de nuevas formas de organización física de la ciudad, de componentes económicos, de formas de gobierno y de relacionarse con las regiones circundantes. Desde un punto de vista físico, la práctica implica centrarse en el núcleo de la ciudad, en sus barrios más importantes y en la gestión del suelo vacante. Desde el punto de vista económico, supone restaurar el rol económico de la ciudad según sus ventajas comparativas y sus bienes existentes, compartir los beneficios del crecimiento con la población y reforzar las conexiones con la región en la que se encuentra la ciudad. Las ciudades también deben fortalecer sus formas de gobierno y ocuparse de que la provisión de servicios y de recursos fiscales entre la ciudad y los municipios del área metropolitana sea fluida.

Las ciudades industriales tradicionales han experimentado un deterioro en las últimas décadas, por lo que su recuperación llevará tiempo e implicará una buena dosis de paciencia. Aunque el funcionamiento de algunas de estas ciudades, tales como Camden, Nueva Jersey, continúa disminuyendo, otras ciudades están mostrando signos de progreso. En Pittsburgh, Filadelfia, Milwaukee y otras ciudades industriales tradicionales que se están recuperando, el rendimiento económico ha mejorado y las tasas de desempleo, delincuencia y pobreza se han reducido por debajo de los promedios nacionales, a pesar del hecho de que las poblaciones permanecen bastante por debajo del pico al que habían llegado unos 60 años atrás.

Para obtener información adicional sobre los factores determinantes del éxito de las ciudades tradicionales, ver: http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/2215_Regenerating-America-s-Legacy-Cities.

¿Cómo proporcionan los estados alivio tributario?

Un estudio nacional sobre exenciones a la vivienda familiar y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad
Adam H. Langley, Abril 1, 2015

El impuesto sobre la propiedad es el tributo más impopular de los Estados Unidos. Los estados han respondido a esta oposición pública promulgando una serie de políticas de alivio fiscal, especialmente para propietarios de vivienda (Cabral y Hoxby 2012). Entre los programas más comúnmente adoptados se encuentran las exenciones para la vivienda familiar (en inglés, homestead exemption) y los créditos al impuesto sobre la propiedad; todos los estados salvo tres cuentan por lo menos con uno de estos programas. Pero a pesar de su uso generalizado y su impacto potencialmente grande sobre la distribución de la carga del impuesto sobre la propiedad, hay muy pocos datos disponibles sobre los ahorros tributarios generados por las exenciones y los créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad.

Dos nuevos recursos, disponibles en Características significativas del impuesto sobre la propiedad, subcentro de la página web del Instituto Lincoln, comienzan a satisfacer esta necesidad. Estas tablas proporcionan información para cada estado sobre el porcentaje de propietarios elegibles para estos programas y el nivel de ahorros tributarios que reciben, además de un análisis de cómo la elegibilidad y los beneficios varían en función de la distribución de ingresos (ver recuadro 1, pág. 32). Este artículo utiliza estos recursos para proporcionar el primer estudio nacional de exenciones y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad, con estimaciones de los ahorros tributarios obtenidos de estos programas. Con esta información, los dirigentes políticos cuentan con una herramienta fundamental para evaluar y mejorar la efectividad de sus programas de alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad.

————————

Recuadro 1: Detalles por estado de exenciones y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad

El subcentro del sitio web del Instituto Lincoln Características significativas del impuesto sobre la propiedad proporciona tres recursos clave de información sobre las exenciones y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad en los 50 estados de los EE.UU. Se puede acceder a este subcentro en www.lincolninst.edu/subcenters/significant-features-property-tax.

Ahorros tributarios por exenciones y créditos de impuestos

Este archivo Excel en línea incluye estimaciones de ahorros tributarios por programas en cada estado (ver el ejemplo abreviado a continuación) más tablas resumen que facilitan la comparación entre estados. El archivo proporciona estimaciones sobre la cantidad de propietarios elegibles y la mediana del beneficio para cada programa, así como un análisis distributivo por quintil de ingresos. Esta es la primera vez que se dispone de datos detallados para la mayoría de estos programas.

Tabla resumen de exenciones y créditos

Este archivo Excel incluye un conjunto de tablas de 167 programas que muestra el valor de las exenciones expresadas en términos de valor de mercado, criterios relacionados con la edad, discapacidad, ingresos, condición de veterano de guerra, el tipo de impuestos afectado (es decir, impuestos escolares o de condado), si la pérdida de recaudación tributaria es absorbida por el gobierno estatal o los gobiernos locales, opciones locales, etc. La tabla resumen permite efectuar fácilmente un análisis cuantitativo de estos programas o comparar rápidamente un estado con otro. La información de estas tablas se usó para generar las estimaciones de ahorros tributarios.

Alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad residencial

Esta sección del sitio web Características significativas incluye descripciones detalladas de las exenciones y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad que se usaron para crear la tabla resumen sobre exenciones y créditos. También describe otros tipos de alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad, tales como programas de desgravación y de prórroga tributaria.

Notas: Los ahorros tributarios totales de la exención del impuesto sobre la propiedad por vivienda familiar para adultos mayores y discapacitados (US$392 millones) es menor que el total combinado de los programas para adultos mayores (US$378 millones) y discapacitados (US$22 millones), porque los propietarios que tienen más de 65 años y están discapacitados no pueden reclamar la exención dos veces. La tabla resumen en línea muestra que la exención para adultos mayores y discapacitados es de US$25.000 para propietarios que tienen más de 65 de años de edad o están discapacitados; los dos programas retroactivos son exenciones porcentuales del 2,5% y 10% para todas las residencias ocupadas por sus dueños. Fuente: Instituto Lincoln de Políticas de Suelo (2015).

————————

Cómo funcionan las exenciones y los créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad

Los programas de alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad adoptan diversas formas. Las exenciones por vivienda familiar reducen el valor de la propiedad sujeta al tributo, ya sea por un monto fijo en dólares o por un porcentaje del valor de la vivienda. Los créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad, en contraste, reducen directamente de la factura de cobro un monto fijo o un cierto porcentaje.

Como se ilustra en la tabla 1, los programas diseñados para proporcionar beneficios idénticos a propietarios de viviendas de US$200.000 tienen un impacto muy distinto en los propietarios de viviendas de alto valor que en los de viviendas de bajo valor. Dada una tasa tributaria del 1%, una exención de importe fijo de US$20.000 reduce el impuesto sobre la propiedad para cada hogar en US$200 (US$20.000 x 1%). Este programa tiene un impacto progresivo en la distribución del impuesto sobre la propiedad porque las unidades familiares de menores ingresos tienden a tener viviendas de valor menor, y la exención representa un porcentaje mayor del valor de sus viviendas. En este caso, la exención de US$20.000 reduce el impuesto sobre la propiedad un 20% en una vivienda de US$100.000, 10% en una vivienda de US$200.000 y un 5% en una vivienda de US$400.000.

Una exención porcentual, por el contrario, proporciona la misma reducción porcentual en el impuesto para los tres propietarios del ejemplo: 10%. En dólares, sin embargo, las exenciones porcentuales favorecen a los propietarios de viviendas de mayor valor: una reducción generalizada del 10% reduce el impuesto sobre la propiedad en sólo US$100 para una vivienda de US$100.000, pero US$400 para una vivienda de US$400.000.

En el caso de créditos de importe fijo, los propietarios con viviendas de menor valor en general reciben los descuentos tributarios mayores en términos porcentuales. Por el contrario, el crédito tributario porcentual proporciona al propietario de una vivienda de US$400.000 el mayor descuento tributario al calcularse en dólares.

Una característica importante de las exenciones y los créditos porcentuales del impuesto sobre la propiedad es que la reducción en dólares (pero no la reducción porcentual) del impuesto aumenta con las tasas tributarias. Por ejemplo, si las viviendas de la tabla 1 fueran objeto de una tasa tributaria del 2%, el ahorro en dólares para sus propietarios sería el doble bajo la exención de US$20.000, la exención del 10% y el crédito del 10%. Si bien el ahorro en dólares de los créditos de importe fijo no varía con las tasas tributarias, el ahorro porcentual para los propietarios disminuye a medida que crecen las tasas tributarias.

Características esenciales de las exenciones y los créditos

El diseño de los programas de exención para viviendas familiares y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad varía significativamente en los 50 estados. La figura 1 hace un resumen de la cantidad y el porcentaje de programas estatales con las siguientes características claves.

Cálculo del beneficio

Quizás la característica más importante de los programas de alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad es cómo se calculan los beneficios. En 2012, el 59% de los programas estatales proporcionaban exenciones de importe fijo, el 19% proporcionaban exenciones porcentuales, y el quinto restante usó créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad u otras fórmulas más complicadas para determinar la cantidad de alivio tributario para cada propietario.

Si bien los programas funcionan de manera similar, sus efectos difieren considerablemente. Como se muestra en los ejemplos de la tabla 1, las exenciones y créditos de importe fijo hacen que la distribución del impuesto sobre la propiedad sea más progresiva, mientras que las exenciones y los créditos porcentuales no lo son. En consecuencia, para proporcionar un cierto nivel de alivio tributario para la mediana de propietarios, las exenciones porcentuales son más caras que otros programas porque se traducen en descuentos mayores en el impuesto sobre la propiedad para los propietarios de viviendas de mayor valor. En vez de cambiar la distribución del impuesto sobre la propiedad entre los propietarios, las exenciones porcentuales son principalmente una manera de desplazar la carga tributaria de los propietarios, como grupo, a las empresas, los inquilinos y propietarios de más de una vivienda.

Financiamiento estatal vs. local

El impacto final de las exenciones y los créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad en las facturas de cobro depende de cómo se financian los programas. La figura 1 muestra que en 2012 sólo el 28% de estos programas recibía un reembolso íntegro por parte del estado para cubrir las pérdidas de ingresos locales, mientras que en el 57% de los casos los gobiernos locales tenían que absorber las pérdidas de ingresos. En el 15% de los programas, el gobierno estatal y los gobiernos locales compartieron las pérdidas de ingresos de alguna manera. (Los programas generalizados para todos los propietarios o todos los adultos mayores tienen una mayor probabilidad de recibir financiamiento estatal que los programas para grupos más pequeños, como los veteranos de guerra o los discapacitados. En 2012, el 43% de los programas de alivio tributario para todos los propietarios o adultos mayores fue financiado por el estado, el 48% fue financiado localmente y el resto dividió la pérdida de ingresos [Instituto Lincoln de Políticas de Suelo, 2014]).

El argumento principal a favor del financiamiento estatal de las exenciones y los créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad es que pueden ayudar a mitigar las disparidades de riqueza inmobiliaria entre distintas localidades. Las comunidades más pobres y aquellas sin una base tributaria significativa tienen tasas normalmente más altas de impuesto sobre la propiedad, y estas comunidades reciben más fondos por propietario de los programas financiados por el estado. Sin esta ayuda, las comunidades con mayores tasas tributarias experimentarán una pérdida mayor de ingresos debido a los programas de alivio tributario, a menos que aumenten sus tasas tributarias aún más.

Adultos mayores vs. grupos de todas las edades

Ciertos estados proporcionan alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad a los adultos mayores. En 2012, más de un tercio de los estados favorecieron de alguna manera a los adultos mayores: siete tenían programas estatales exclusivamente para este grupo, mientras que 11 cubrían también a propietarios más jóvenes, pero proporcionaba más beneficios a los propietarios adultos mayores. Otros estados o bien proporcionaron la misma cantidad de beneficios a propietarios de todas las edades (15 estados), o bien no tenían programas generalizados (18 estados).

Los argumentos más comunes para beneficiar a los propietarios mayores son que el impuesto sobre la propiedad consume un porcentaje más alto de sus ingresos y que los gobiernos locales gastan menos en los adultos mayores que en propietarios más jóvenes con hijos en edad escolar. Si bien es cierto que el impuesto sobre la propiedad representa un porcentaje más alto de los ingresos para los adultos mayores que para los propietarios que son trabajadores activos, los dos grupos dedican una proporción casi idéntica de sus ingresos a gastos totales de vivienda, porque es mucho menos probable que los adultos mayores estén pagando una hipoteca (Bowman et al. 2009, 11). Además, el impuesto sobre la propiedad es un pago por servicios públicos, no un arancel de uso (Kenyon 2007, 36). Los hogares compuestos por personas más jóvenes sin hijos en las escuelas públicas no se benefician del alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad bajo estos programas. El tratamiento tributario preferencial de los adultos mayores puede reflejar simplemente que los hogares formados por personas mayores forman un grupo políticamente poderoso que tiende a votar masivamente.

Estimación de los beneficios de exenciones y créditos

Para estimar los ahorros tributarios de las exenciones de la vivienda familiar y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad, el primer paso fue crear la Tabla de resumen de exenciones y créditos en línea, que describe las características clave de cada programa (ver el recuadro 1 para una descripción). Estos datos se extraen casi por completo de la sección Programas de alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad residencial de la base de datos Características significativas del impuesto sobre la propiedad del Instituto Lincoln.

El segundo paso fue combinar esta información con los datos a nivel familiar de la Encuesta de Comunidades Americanas (American Community Survey o ACS) de 2008–2012. Esta encuesta nacionalmente representativa tiene datos sobre más de 6,5 millones de hogares en los EE.UU., incluyendo las características de las familias que determinan su elegibilidad para el programa (edad, ingresos, discapacidad, condición de veteranía de guerra, etc.) y el nivel de beneficios recibidos (valores de las viviendas y montos del impuesto sobre la propiedad). Para una explicación completa de la metodología utilizada para estimar los ahorros tributarios de exenciones y créditos, ver Langley (2015).

Es importante hacer notar que las estimaciones registradas aquí son ahorros brutos en el impuesto sobre la propiedad. Los programas de alivio tributario frecuentemente resultan en un aumento de las tasas del impuesto sobre la propiedad, sobre todo en los programas financiados localmente, en los que las jurisdicciones aumentan las tasas tributarias para compensar la pérdida de la base tributable debida a las exenciones. Las estimaciones de ahorros netos en el impuesto sobre la propiedad serían menores en aquellas comunidades, debido a que las mayores tasas tributarias contrarrestarían parcialmente el alivio tributario directo debido a las exenciones y créditos.

La figura 2 (pág. 35) muestra que el alivio total del impuesto sobre la propiedad debido a las exenciones de vivienda familiar y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad varía mucho entre estados, pero en general es pequeño con relación a los ingresos totales por ese concepto. En 14 de los 45 estados que tienen estos programas, los ahorros totales son menos del 0,5% de la recaudación total del impuesto sobre la propiedad; en 27 estados, los ahorros son menos del 2,5%. Por otro lado, los ahorros tributarios en nueve estados son mayores o iguales al 10% de los ingresos totales del impuesto sobre la propiedad. El programa de Indiana es particularmente generoso, ya que ofrece a todos los propietarios una exención de US$45.000, y después una exención adicional del 35% para los primeros US$600.000 de valuación fiscal y una exención del 25% para las valuaciones que superan los US$600.000.

Ahorros tributarios por distintos tipos de programas

La mayoría de los estados tienen más de un programa de exención o crédito del impuesto sobre la propiedad, dirigidos a distintos grupos de contribuyentes: normalmente, a todos los propietarios, a los mayores, a los veteranos de guerra o a los discapacitados. La figura 3 (pág. 36) presenta estimaciones de la proporción de propietarios elegibles para estos programas, junto con el nivel de ahorros tributarios que reciben.

Propietarios

En 26 estados hay programas que cubren a la casi totalidad de los propietarios, pero en general están limitados a la primera vivienda ocupada por sus propietarios. En los programas para un estado típico, la mediana del valor que cada propietario recibe es un descuento del 12,5% en su impuesto sobre la propiedad. En el extremo superior, sin embargo, la mediana del descuento del impuesto sobre la propiedad fue de al menos un 25% en más de un cuarto de los estados que tenían estos programas.

Adultos mayores

18 estados cuentan con programas de alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad para propietarios mayores (normalmente a partir de 65 años de edad). Estos programas son mucho más generosos que aquellos que cubren a todos los propietarios, con una mediana de reducción tributaria de casi el 30% en un estado típico. Más de la mitad de estos programas proporcionan una mediana de descuento de por lo menos el 25%, y sólo un sexto de ellos tienen una mediana de descuento de menos del 10%.

En la mediana de los estados, el 19,6% de los propietarios son elegibles para los programas, pero las tasas de elegibilidad varían mucho entre un estado y otro, dependiendo de si hay un límite de ingresos. En los siete estados que proporcionan alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad a los adultos mayores sin tener en cuenta el nivel de ingresos, normalmente un 25–30% de los propietarios son elegibles. Pero en siete estados con programas sólo para propietarios de bajos ingresos (límites entre US$10.000 y US$30.000), sólo del 5 al 10% de los propietarios son elegibles. Los otros cuatro estados con programas de alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad para adultos mayores no se pueden clasificar en ninguna de estas dos categorías, porque marcan un tope de ingresos, ponen límites estrictos de riqueza u otros criterios de elegibilidad.

Veteranos de guerra

Los programas estatales para veteranos de guerra están más extendidos que para cualquier otro grupo de propietarios, aun cuando la elegibilidad frecuentemente está limitada a los discapacitados. En efecto, sólo 10 estados proporcionan exenciones o créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad para todos los veteranos, incluso a aquellos sin discapacidades. En la mediana de los estados para estos programas, el beneficiario típico recibe un descuento en el impuesto sobre la propiedad de sólo el 3,2%.

Hay 31 estados que proporcionan exenciones o créditos al impuesto sobre la propiedad a veteranos de guerra con discapacidades relacionadas con su servicio en las Fuerzas Armadas. Debido al requisito de discapacidad, la mayoría de los veteranos de guerra no son elegibles para estos programas. En efecto, sólo el 15% de los veteranos de guerra son elegibles en el estado típico. En general, sólo el 0,6% de los propietarios son elegibles para estos programas en la mediana de los estados.

Más aún, la mayoría de los 31 programas determinan la elegibilidad y los niveles de beneficio aplicando la graduación de discapacidad del Departamento de Asuntos de Veteranos. Sólo siete estados tienen programas para todos los veteranos parcialmente discapacitados, y aquellos con un grado de discapacidad menor normalmente reciben descuentos tributarios modestos. Por otro lado, 18 estados restringen la elegibilidad a veteranos de guerra que sufren discapacidad permanente y total. Estos programas benefician a una proporción muy pequeña de veteranos de guerra, pero en general les proporciona una exención completa del impuesto sobre la propiedad.

Discapacitados

23 estados tienen programas para los propietarios discapacitados, pero en realidad están dirigidos a dos grupos distintos: los propietarios discapacitados y los propietarios invidentes. En 2012, 12 estados tenían programas para propietarios discapacitados, siete estados tenían programas para los invidentes y cinco estados cubrían a ambos grupos. Los programas para discapacitados normalmente exigen que los beneficiarios tengan una discapacidad permanente y total, pero los criterios exactos varían. En la mediana de los estados, el 2,3% de los propietarios son elegibles para estos programas y reciben una mediana de descuento en el impuesto sobre la propiedad del 21%.

Conclusión

Las exenciones para vivienda familiar y los créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad son una parte importante del sistema de impuestos sobre la propiedad. Estos programas se usan en casi todos los estados y pueden resultar en una distribución de impuestos sobre la propiedad mucho más progresiva. Por lo tanto, es fundamental que los dirigentes políticos dispongan de datos fidedignos sobre el alivio del impuesto sobre la propiedad que estos programas proporcionan realmente.

Por primera vez, nuevas investigaciones permiten disponer de esta información. Mediante el uso del subcentro web Características significativas del impuesto sobre la propiedad del Instituto Lincoln, los dirigentes políticos pueden comparar fácilmente las características clave de los programas de exención y crédito del impuesto sobre la propiedad en los distintos estados, y consultar las estimaciones de elegibilidad y ahorros tributarios. Estos datos permiten evaluar el impacto de las exenciones y créditos del impuesto sobre la propiedad en cada estado en particular, así como encontrar ideas para mejorar los programas.

Adam H. Langley es Analista de Investigación Senior del Instituto Lincoln de Políticas de Suelo. Un agradecimiento especial para Andrew Reschovsky, quien proporcionó exhaustivos comentarios sobre este artículo y otros documentos relacionados.

Referencias

Bowman, John H., Daphne A. Kenyon, Adam Langley, and Bethany P. Paquin. 2009. Property Tax Circuit Breakers: Fair and Cost-Effective Relief for Taxpayers. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Cabral, Marika, and Caroline Hoxby. 2012. “The Hated Property Tax: Salience, Tax Rates, and Tax Revolts.” Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Working paper 18514. November.

Kenyon, Daphne A. 2007. The Property Tax-School Funding Dilemma. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Langley, Adam H. 2015. “Estimating Tax Savings from Homestead Exemptions and Property Tax Credits.” Working paper. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. 2014. Significant Features of the Property Tax. Residential Property Tax Relief Programs: Summary Table on Exemptions and Credits in 2012. www.lincolninst.edu/subcenters/significant-features-property-tax/Report_Residential_Property_Tax_Relief_Programs.aspx

Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. 2015. Significant Features of the Property Tax. Tax Savings from Property Tax Exemptions and Credits in 2012. www.lincolninst.edu/subcenters/significant-features-property-tax/Report_Residential_Property_Tax_Relief_Programs.aspx

Lessons from the Latin American Experience with Value Capture

Martim Smolka and Fernanda Furtado, Julio 1, 2001

Over the past five years, the Lincoln Institute has supported the study of value capture policies and instruments in many Latin American countries. Notwithstanding the diversity of approaches and the variety of specific cases, we have identified seven substantive lessons that can help to clarify some of the confusion and misunderstandings associated with the implementation of value capture principles. Each lesson summarized below presents one or two examples drawn from the book, Recuperación de Plusvalías en América Latina: Alternativas para el Desarrollo Urbano.

Value capture refers to the process by which all or a portion of increments in land value attributed to “community efforts” rather than landowner actions are recovered by the public sector. These “unearned increments” may be captured indirectly through their conversion into public revenues as taxes, fees, exactions or other fiscal means, or directly through on-site improvements to benefit the community at large.

1. Value capture is not a new concept in Latin America. The Latin American experience with value capture has long-standing historical precedents. Public debates on the use of value capture and related instruments have been held since the beginning of the twentieth century in several countries. In the 1920s, the debate was triggered by concrete events, such as the problem of paving streets in São Paulo, Brazil, and the lack of external financing for needed public works in Colombia. In other cases, political and ideological factors have motivated national discussions. Representatives of the Partido Radical in Chile made several attempts to introduce the idea, and in the 1930s President Aguirre Cerda proposed legislation to create a national tax on plusvalías (land value increments) based on the ideas of Henry George.

2. However, its application in the urban policy agenda is still limited. Despite many reports of relevant experiences that integrate the principles of value capture, the issue is not well represented or even sufficiently acknowledged within the sphere of urban policy. In some instances, promising value capture initiatives have gained prominence in their own times, only to be forgotten later. An important example is the well-known Lander Report from Venezuela, which proposed in the 1960s that land and its increments in value should be the main source of financing for urban development projects. That report formed the basis for recommendations on urban development finance included in the proceedings of Habitat I (1976).

In other cases, interesting opportunities to use value capture as a tool for urban policy are being lost or ignored. Currently some Latin American countries are not taking advantage of potential unearned land value increments generated by major inner-city revitalization projects. While there is general acceptance of the notion of capturing increases in land values, in reality little of that increased value derived from public action has actually been recovered and redistributed.

3. Legislation often exists but is not implemented. As in many other countries in the region, the variety of value capture instruments available in Mexico, ranging from the contribución por mejoras (a special assessment or betterment levy aimed at recovering the costs of public works) to taxes on plusvalías, illustrates the discrepancy between what is legally possible and what is actually implemented. Contrary to what is often alleged, the general problem is not that the planners or local officials lack legal or practical access to these instruments but that the following conditions tend to prevail.

  • The legislation and instruments are often conceived and designed (sometimes intentionally) in such confusing and contradictory ways that they virtually paralyze any operational policy initiatives. For example, the Venezuelan national expropriation law of 1947 prescribes the taxation of 75 percent of land value increments related to public works, whereas the general municipal constitution (Ley Orgánica de Régimen Municipal) limits taxation to 5 percent of the total value of the affected property. In reality, even this limited charge is not collected.
  • Even when the law makes value capture feasible, it may be difficult to interpret. For example, the debate between eminent jurists in the l970s in Brazil with respect to the constitutionality of the legislation on solo criado (an instrument based on the separation of land and building rights) reflected a basic lack of understanding of legal precedents regarding value capture and its associated instruments.
  • The possibilities of the law are not always widely known, even in their respective countries. This seems to be the case in Mexico, where the traditional property tax in the city of Mexicali, based on the combined value of land and buildings, was successfully replaced by a tax based exclusively on land value (Perlo 1999). Other cities in Mexico do not seem to be aware of or have not taken advantage of similar provisions in their state’s legislation.

4. Resistance is more ideological than logical. Even when value capture legislation and instruments are understood (or in some cases because they are understood), they may not be implemented fully due to the proverbial “lack of political will.” This resistance may take the form of misleading interpretations, stereotyped rationalizations and even pure ideological “preaching.”

It is not hard to find public justification that the application of such instruments is neither timely nor appropriate, especially if the justification is based on misleading interpretations. Some such arguments are that impositions on land values are inflationary and disruptive of well-functioning markets, or that they incur unacceptable taxation of the same base twice. Such misconceptions seem to lie behind the reluctance of the Ministry of Housing and Urbanism of Chile to promote the review and resubmission to the Congress of some value capture provisions in the country’s new legal framework on urbanism.

Objections based on stereotyped rationalizations may use the following arguments:

  • the corresponding revenues are not significant or are not justified when compared with the administrative costs incurred;
  • the public administrations would not be competent in terms of technical and human resources; or
  • the application of value capture instruments would be antisocial and regressive, since the poor population, which has the greatest need for more urban infrastructure, has the least capacity to pay.

Contradicting these arguments, however, are the development of successful participatory improvement programs in poor areas of many cities (for instance in Chile, Brazil and Peru). These programs have been technically and economically efficient and usually have strong support from the low-income population affected.

Finally, some objections are of a purely ideological nature. The resistance to the implementation of participación en plusvalías in Colombia, for example, is based on the allegation that this device, although recognized as technically well-formulated, represents one more unwanted public “interference” on urban real estate business, such as a higher fiscal burden, limitations on property rights or more regulation (Barco de Botero and Smolka 2000). This position has been replaced recently by a broad consensus among politicians, business leaders and the general public that acceptance of this instrument is a better option than the imposition of additional property taxes.

5. Value capture is gradually becoming more popular. In spite of the obstacles and political resistance, recent Latin American experience with value capture shows a growing interest in the subject and in the conditions that would justify its utilization. Value capture is attracting the attention of municipal planners throughout the region, and it is beginning to be perceived as an important urban policy initiative. This growing popularity is related to several factors occurring in the region.

First, greater administrative and fiscal decentralization requires more autonomy in redefining and obtaining alternative sources of public funds to finance the urbanization process. The need for more local resources has been reinforced by the social demands and political pressures associated with current redemocratization processes and growing levels of popular participation. Formation of extra-budget funds to finance special social programs is linked to almost all new value capture initiatives and has been one of the most attractive reasons for implementing those policies.

Second, the redefinition of the functions of the state (including privatization), together with the decline of comprehensive planning, have set the stage for the development of more flexible public interventions and direct negotiations in land use regulation and public-private partnerships. The release of public areas to the private land market, as well as better coordination between real estate and public sector interests to promote new areas in the cities, are also significant. It is worth noting that even in Cuba one finds a vigorous program through which the Office of the Historian in Havana, operating as a kind of property holding company, refinances its state-owned operations with land value increments resulting from urban renovation projects in the form of rents charged to private development “partners” (Nuñez, Brown and Smolka 2000).

Other favorable factors include the conditions imposed by the agendas of the multilateral agencies, which clearly promote the universalization of user charges and the recovery of the costs of public investments. The growing popularity of new value capture instruments can also be attributed to some frustration with the poor results obtained from the application of taxes and other traditional charges related to urban land in past decades, in terms of both revenues and urban policy objectives.

6. Pragmatism overrides ethical or theoretical justifications. A corollary to the preceding point is that the growing popularity of value capture seems to be inspired more by eminently pragmatic reasons than by ethical criteria, notions of equality, or theoretical and political justifications. Some reforms may even have been introduced without full political awareness of the process, or of its theoretical importance, as previously illustrated in the Mexicali case. The historical evidence shows that most value capture initiatives have responded above all to the need to face fiscal crises and other local problems in the financing of urban development. This is the case even in Argentina, where the need for revenues prevailed over established principles opposed to new taxes when a temporary five-percent increase in the property tax was used as one of the initiatives to finance investments in the new Buenos Aires subway system.

Nevertheless, one should not assume from the above examples that accumulation of experience is not important for the refinement of instruments and the evolution of value capture policies. A case in point is the Colombian experience with the contribución de valorización since the 1920s and the many attempts to overcome some of its limitations, especially in the past 40 years. The recently enacted participación en plusvalías is a more technically developed and politically acceptable version of an instrument targeted to capture the sometimes huge land value increments associated with administrative decisions concerning zoning, density levels and other urbanistic norms and regulations.

7. Value capture is not necessarily progressive or redistributive. It must be noted that the reference to plusvalías is in no way a monopoly of the political left. Both Argentina’s and Chile’s recent experiences show clearly the disposition toward the subject in neo-liberal contexts. In addition, the operacões interligadas (linkage operations) developed in São Paulo, and effectively applied by administrations of opposing political and ideological tendencies, put forward a convincing argument about the impossibility of labeling these instruments in advance.

Progressive local governments, on the other hand, are sometimes reluctant to apply these instruments, and may even reject the notion altogether, for three reasons. First, they may believe that such contributions would be simply a mechanism to impose additional fiscal charges with no redistributive impact whatsoever. Second, even when the resulting revenues are earmarked for the low-income population, they may be insufficient to reduce the absolute differences between rich and poor in the access to the serviced land (Furtado 2000). And third is the intergenerational argument that such charges are being imposed on newer, generally poor, residents who need services, whereas earlier generations were not charged for infrastructure services or amenities.

Thus, the progressive nature of such policies is not resolved by “taxing” land value increments or by focusing on high-income taxpayers. The “Robin Hood” image of such policies fades once it becomes clear that the part of the value actually captured in this way tends to be only a fraction, and often a small one, of what the owner actually receives in benefits. This point seems to have been well understood by many lower-income populations, like those in Lima where a successful program featuring some 30 projects used the contribución de mejoras to finance public works in the early 1990s.

This example and other strong evidence support the need to revisit the conventional wisdom regarding the tension between the principles of benefit and capacity of payment. In practice, the strategy of attracting some public intervention to one’s neighborhood (even if it means paying for its costs) is more advantageous than the alternative of being neglected. This point should, nevertheless, be taken with caution, in light of certain experiences where the contribución de mejoras has been applied in low-income areas with purposes other than benefiting the occupants-for example, to justify the eviction or force the departure of those who cannot pay for the improvements (Everett 1999).

Final Considerations

In spite of the difficulties in interpretation and resistance to implementation outlined above, value capture policies are undeniably arousing new interest and growing acceptance. Efforts to utilize value capture have grown in both number and creativity, and its virtues beyond being an alternative source of public financing are becoming better understood. Public administrations are realizing the “market value” of their prerogative to control land use rights, as well as to define the location and timing of public works. They also see that the transparent negotiation of land use and density ratios reduces the margin of transactions that used to be carried out “under the table.” As the link between public intervention and land value increment is becoming more visible, attitudes are changing to be more conducive to building a fiscal culture that will strengthen property taxes and local revenues in general.

However, there is still much to be done in two spheres: researching the complex nature of value capture policies and promoting greater understanding among public officials with regard to how it can be used to benefit their communities. More knowledge is required on certain Latin American idiosyncrasies, such as when significant land value increments are generated under alternative land tenure regimes that are outside the protection of the state, and in cases where the land represents an important mechanism of capitalization for the poor.

Beyond the traditional, structural constraints of patrimonialism, corruption, hidden interests, ideological insensitivity and the like, a considerable part of the “unexplained variance” in different experiences with value capture in Latin America can be attributed to lack of information. Toward that end of improving understanding of the principles and implementation of value capture, there remain many opportunities to document and analyze current experiences with alternative land valuation and taxation instruments.

Martim Smolka is a senior fellow and the director of the Lincoln Institute’s Latin American Program, and Fernanda Furtado is a fellow of the Institute and a professor in the Postgraduate Program in Urbanism at the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro.

References

Barco de Botero, Carolina, and Martim Smolka. 2000.Challenges in Implementing Colombia’s Participación en Plusvalías. Land Lines 12 (March):4-7.

Everett, Margaret. 1999. Human Rights and Evictions of the Urban Poor in Colombia. Land Lines 11 (November):6-8.

Furtado, Fernanda. 2000. Rethinking Value Capture Policies for Latin America. Land Lines 12 (May):8-10.

Nuñez, Ricardo, H. James Brown, and Martim Smolka. 2000. Using Land Value to Promote Development in Cuba. Land Lines 12 (March):1-4.

Perlo Cohen, Manuel. 1999. Mexicali: A Success Story of Property Tax Reform. Land Lines 11 (September):6-7.

Land Prices, Land Markets, and the Broader Economy

Stephen K. Mayo, Marzo 1, 1998

The interactions between land and property markets and the broader economy of cities and nations are central to the Lincoln Institute’s concerns. Two key objectives of our work in this area are (1) to raise awareness about the stakes of good land policy for creating well-functioning land and property markets and for improving the performance of financial markets, labor markets, the fiscal affairs of local and national governments, and ultimately the economic health of both cities and countries; and (2) to indicate the need for high quality data and an appropriate analytical framework to aid in understanding the importance of good land policy, monitoring the effects of land policies throughout the economy and facilitating policy reforms. In November 1997, the Lincoln Institute held a conference on the theme of “Land Prices, Information Systems, and the Market for Land Information” to explore these issues.

Land Values and Land Policy

How important are the stakes of good land policy? Hee-Nam Jung of the Korean Research Institute for Human Settlements reported on the importance of land markets in the economies of five countries (see Table 1). The value of land in mature economies such as Canada, France and the United States ranged from about one-third to three-quarters of GNP during the mid-1980s, and represented from 8 to 21 percent of estimated national wealth. In the more rapidly growing economies of Japan and Korea, land values were from three to six times as high as GNP in the 1980s, and represented half or more of estimated national wealth. In the mature economies these figures illustrate the importance of land as a source of wealth, but in rapidly growing economies land has an even more significant role in determining economic welfare and a host of incentives for the performance of the economy.

In Japan, for example, booming land and property values during the 1980s served as collateral to fund credit expansion throughout the economy and, indeed, throughout the world. Land prices in Japan’s six largest cities increased dramatically from 1980 to 1991, at a compound rate of about 12 percent annually (see Figure 1). By 1990, the estimated price of land being developed for residential purposes in Tokyo was estimated to be about $3,000 per square meter, compared to figures of roughly $110 in Toronto and Paris and $70 in Washington, D.C.

Between 1991 and 1996, however, Japanese land prices fell by nearly half, taking down the Japanese economy and a host of financial institutions in its wake. The cumulative losses of the Japanese banking system associated with the collapse of the property market and associated businesses are estimated around $1 trillion, making the U.S. Savings and Loan “crisis” seem comparatively insignificant. Analysis of Japanese land policy suggests some of the causes of the boom and bust cycle in land prices: policies that have severely restricted conversion of agricultural land to urban uses; an especially complex land development system that requires exceptionally long times for approvals; and a fiscal system that places little emphasis on the taxation of land and property values.

Land prices in Korea also rose at a tremendous rate during the 1980s-over 16 percent annually from 1981 to 1991. Remarkably, in most years nominal capital gains on Korean land were greater than Korea’s GNP. Jung explained that these gains had profound implications for the distribution of wealth and income in Korea, and for economic incentives. Not surprisingly, the recent collapse of Korean property markets has had tidal effects throughout the economy. As in the case of Japan, the Korean land policy framework has been seen as highly questionable. Government intervention in land and property markets over the years has been responsible for severely distorted markets that represent a major structural imbalance in the Korean economy.

Using Land Market Data for Policy Analysis

Other speakers at the conference presented information on the importance of land market performance for a variety of stakeholders throughout the economy: consumers and taxpayers; land developers and builders of residential and non-residential properties; banks and financial institutions; and both local and central governments. In the case of Cracow, Poland, Alain Bertaud from the World Bank indicated that policies embodied in master plans and zoning regulations were highly inconsistent with the nominal objectives of the regulations, and would lead to inefficient and costly spatial patterns within the city. His paper illustrated the value of having good data on land prices, regulations and the spatial distribution of the population in order to evaluate the effects of policies involving land use, infrastructure and property taxation.

Paul Cheshire from Oberlin College and Stephen Sheppard from the London School of Economics illustrated how data on land and housing prices, land and housing characteristics, and regulations can be used to evaluate the effects of government policies such as the preservation of urban open space. Jean-Paul Blandinieres of the French Ministry of Equipment, Transportation and Housing discussed an ambitious program of the French government to establish “Urban Observatories” to collect and analyze information on land and property markets and the effects of government policies.

Data Collection on Land and Property Markets

Recognition of the costs of land policy failures or, conversely, of the benefits associated with implementing good policies, has given rise to a number of systematic efforts to collect and analyze high quality data on land and property markets within various institutional settings. Pablo Trivelli discussed land and property information systems in Latin America that serve the needs of public and private stakeholders. Perhaps the most impressive of these is an effort in Brazil called EMBRAESP, which monitors key indicators of urban property market performance along with urban legislation, land regulations and major public works projects that might have an impact on the behavior of property markets. Data and analyses from EMBRAESP are of interest to many institutions throughout Brazil. The distribution of the information is self-sustaining through contracts with major newspaper chains, sales of periodic bulletins, disks containing standard data, and special reports responding to individual demands. Much of this information can also be accessed through the Internet.

Another major data collection and analysis effort was reported by David Dowall from the University of California-Berkeley. He developed the “Land Market Assessment,” a tool for analysis of land and housing markets that has been applied in over 30 developing countries and transitional economies. At comparatively modest cost, data are collected through aerial photos and satellite images, surveys of land brokers, and secondary sources on population, infrastructure and regulatory frameworks. Dowall’s analysis of the experience with these assessments documents a number of generic policy findings, especially concerning the costs of inappropriate land policies. His work also suggests that even more cost-effective versions of the tool can be developed that will illustrate the workings of land markets and beneficial policy reforms.

Romeo Sherko, David Stanfield and Malcolm Childress from the Land Tenure Center at the University of Wisconsin-Madison, addressed the issue of designing a strategy for the creation and dissemination of land information in transitional economies, where information has historically been tightly held, thus frustrating both the evolution of property markets and opportunities for policy analysis. Their conclusions regarding the role of the public and private sectors, the scope of data collection, and pricing and dissemination strategies help to explain why land market information is often not provided or is poorly provided by either the government or the private sector. On the other hand, their analysis suggests that the benefits of good land market information are considerable. Some of these benefits were illustrated by David Dale-Johnson from the University of Southern California and Jan Brzeski from Jagellonian University, Cracow, who discussed efforts to document rapidly evolving market prices of property in Cracow and to inform property tax reform efforts.

Samu Kurri, Seppo Laakso, and Heikki Loikkanen of the Finnish Government Institute of Economic Research discussed the land price information system in Finland, suggesting that it is only now beginning to catch up with the needs of many different potential users of the data. These users include those concerned with implementation of a new property tax and macro-economic and financial sector policymakers concerned with the interaction of the Finnish property market and national economic performance. Karl (Chip) Case of Wellesley College presented findings from a preliminary analysis of 100 years of land prices in Boston, which was designed, among other things, to highlight some of the methodological difficulties of measuring land prices in a way that facilitates policy analysis and reform.

Stephen K. Mayo is a senior fellow of the Lincoln Institute.

From the President

Gregory K. Ingram, Julio 1, 2005

Education, training, research, and dissemination have been the instruments used most frequently by the Lincoln Institute to achieve its goals of expanding and making available its knowledge of land policy and taxation. Recently the Institute has begun to combine these instruments in demonstration projects, which involve the application of knowledge, data collection, and expertise to the development and implementation of policy in specific circumstances.

Several ongoing projects provide expert advice and assistance to agencies that are considering new approaches to property taxation, planning, or development. Examples include the consideration of property and land tax reform in several states, the management of state-owned lands, land market monitoring, and support for new approaches to urbanization in Latin America.

Moving forward, the scope of Institute demonstration projects will expand to include the analysis of policies as they are being applied and to document their outcomes. The aim of this expansion is to improve our understanding of the effectiveness of new policy initiatives—what works and in what conditions it does so.

Whether a policy works or not is normally defined in terms of the achievement of the policy’s intended objectives. Thus, our approach would be limited to those policies that have well-defined objectives or intended outcomes. Assessing the achievement of outcomes will be based on performance indicators that measure attainment of the policy’s objectives as well as on the change in other relevant parameters.

Perhaps most important, these demonstration projects will require the collection of baseline data before policy implementation begins so that the analysis of policy effects has a valid benchmark for comparison. Many studies of the impact of policies are severely handicapped by a lack of a good baseline from which to measure change.

When a policy intervention is successful in one application, its results are sometimes readily transferable to other environments, but that is not always the case. For example, the effectiveness of property tax policies may vary with institutional factors such as the clarity of a country’s property rights regime or the independence of the assessment appeal process from political pressure. If institutional dimensions are important determinants of policy effectiveness, more than one assessment of a policy application is needed to determine the influence of those factors. The assumption that “one size fits all” is rarely true when institutional details are an important determinant of policy performance—as they often are in land policy and taxation.

Well-documented case studies of the impact of policies can be powerful instruments in the classroom and as evidence in policy debates. Policy makers and many students often find the results of rigorous case studies to be more accessible and compelling. We anticipate that the results of the Institute’s demonstration projects will contribute valuable new material to our education and research programs.

Report from the President

Supporting Land Policy Research in Latin America
Gregory K. Ingram, Abril 1, 2010

To enhance the Lincoln Institute’s commitment to building research capacity on international land policy issues, the Program on Latin America and the Caribbean initiated an expanded effort in 2006 to support research in that region. Since then the Lincoln Institute has issued annual public requests for research proposals that set out the criteria used to evaluate the proposals and a set of priority thematic topics, normally related to land markets, local public finance, and urban development. This year’s priorities include implementation and impacts of land use regulations; land-based instruments to finance urban development; land markets; and urban form.

Most of those who submit research proposals are affiliated with academic institutions throughout Latin America. Other applicants are typically practitioners from government entities, nongovernmental organizations, and private consultancies, as well as scholars working on Latin American themes at universities outside the region. About two-thirds of the proposals submitted and funded are from researchers having no prior affiliation with our Latin America Program, which is consistent with one objective of the research program—to widen the network of those studying land policy issues in the region.

The average size of research project funding has increased over time from around $10,000 in 2006 to about $26,000 at present. Some projects that involve extensive field work to support empirically based research have received larger amounts. Over time the program has also become more competitive, with the number of applications growing from 90 in the first year to 150 currently.

The priority topics and selection criteria are designed to encourage empirical studies, and the 18-month funding cycle allows time for data collection, analysis, and preparation of a final report. Lincoln Institute staff provide technical assistance to many researchers as they finalize their research designs and carry out their work. The participants are also invited to a methods workshop at the beginning of each research project cycle to review survey instrument and sample design, multivariate statistical analysis, experimental methods, and the use of geographic information systems.

At the end of each research project cycle all participants discuss each others’ draft papers at a research seminar. Both the methods workshop and research seminar are highly valued by the researchers, and the events have been offered in Colombia, Argentina, and Costa Rica to facilitate access from different parts of the region. Other training courses offered by the Latin America Program, such as those on urban economics and land market analysis, are also often relevant for those carrying out these research projects.

Selected final research reports are posted as working papers on the Lincoln Institute Web site. Currently 33 final papers are available and another 15 are in process. Many of these papers are downloadable in both English and either Spanish or Portuguese. In addition, seven of the completed research papers have been summarized as Land Lines articles, making their results accessible to a wide audience. This April issue presents one such report on home values in Mexico, and announces the completion of a CD-ROM that compiles more than 80 Land Lines articles that have been translated into Spanish under the title Perspectivas Urbanas.

This research program complements another long-standing Latin America Program initiative that provides support for students working on dissertation and masters theses. The graduate student program is also competitive and based on open requests for proposals. In the past two years, the Lincoln Institute has taken steps to increase the coordination between these two research support initiatives, particularly by coordinating the priority topics and harmonizing the selection criteria. By supporting both emerging graduates and more experienced researchers, these initiatives are developing an extensive network of capable analysts who can advance knowledge about land policy and its consequences in Latin America.

The request for research proposals in 2010 will be posted on the Lincoln Institute’s Web site and distributed electronically by email to those in the region who have registered on our Web site. See page 28 of this Land Lines issue for additional information.

Perfil académico

Sally Powers
Julio 1, 2011