Topic: Mercados de suelo

Curso

Gestión de Instrumentos Base Suelo de Financiamiento para el Desarrollo Urbano en América Latina

Mayo 7, 2018 - Mayo 11, 2018

Lima, Peru

Free, offered in español


Este curso tiene como objetivo fortalecer la capacidad de formación en gestión de la valorización del suelo urbano de educadores en América Latina que enseñan temas de planificación como un vehículo para mejorar la formulación, el debate y la implementación de políticas de suelo. Los participantes, junto a un grupo de profesores de amplia experiencia en el tema, discutirán a través de casos y evidencia empírica los fundamentos de la movilización de plusvalías y los principales dilemas que subyacen las políticas de suelo en América Latina. El curso proveerá herramientas conceptuales y pedagógicas para abordar, desde una perspectiva interdisciplinaria, temas críticos de políticas de suelo que inciden en los incrementos del valor del suelo por concepto de cambios en las normativas urbanísticas o las inversiones en infraestructura urbana y servicios, así como en las mejoras de las ocupaciones precarias y su regularización, y otros factores generadores como las expropiaciones, reajustes de suelo y otros instrumentos.

El público objetivo de este curso de actualización para docentes son principalmente educadores que enseñan temas relacionados con la gestión de la valorización del suelo a planificadores y gestores urbanos en América Latina, ya que se busca encontrar oportunidades para mejorar la currícula y pedagogía utilizada en universidades e instituciones educativas de la región. Sin embargo, también está dirigido a profesionales interesados en urbanismo, planificación, gestión urbana y políticas de suelo.

Bajar la convocatoria


Detalles

Date
Mayo 7, 2018 - Mayo 11, 2018
Application Period
Febrero 7, 2018 - Febrero 26, 2018
Selection Notification Date
Marzo 12, 2018 at 6:00 PM
Location
Lima, Peru
Idioma
español
Costo
Free
Registration Fee
Free
Educational Credit Type
Lincoln Institute certificate

Keywords

valor del suelo, finanzas públicas, desarrollo urbano, recuperación de plusvalías

Map of San Francisco with areas with low percentages of affordable housing indicated in light green.

Place Database

San Francisco’s Affordable Housing Shortage
By Jenna DeAngelo, Enero 25, 2018

In most of San Francisco, indicated by the lightest green areas of the map, only 8.32 percent or less of homes in 2015 were likely to be affordable for a 4-person family earning $81,500, or 80 percent of the Area Median Income (AMI).

View the PDF version of this map for more detail and a key.

Source: The Place Database, www.lincolninst.edu/research-data/data/place-database

Portland

Gentle Infill

Boomtowns Are Making Room for Skinny Homes, Granny Flats, and Other Affordable Housing
By Kathleen McCormick, Enero 25, 2018

Recent news stories routinely feature “hot market” U.S. cities with astronomical housing prices that end up displacing residents with moderate or low incomes. San Francisco’s epic housing battles pit longtime residents against tech workers. In Portland, Oregon, city council extended the state of emergency it declared in 2015 to address the local affordable housing crisis. In Denver, Mayor Michael Hancock pledged $150 million for affordable housing in the next decade. Boston Mayor Martin J. Walsh plans to build 53,000 units by 2030, while neighboring Cambridge adds density in infill areas and near transit. And in Boulder, Colorado, public officials seek to add a host of housing options through an approach they call “gentle infill.” 

“Hot markets exist for many reasons, but in Portland, San Francisco, Boulder, and other cities, housing issues are clearly a result of strong economic development,” says Peter Pollock, FAICP, manager of Western programs for the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. In these places, a jobs-housing imbalance leads to inadequate shelter options. The “gentle” or “sensitive” infill approach is about “trying to find ways to make infill compatible with surroundings to achieve urban design goals and enable production of more housing,” he says. The term also “puts a positive spin on something that may not be universally accepted”—namely, density—“and suggests that we can do a better job.”

While half of all households nationwide are spending more than 30 percent of their income on housing, many residents in hot market cities are spending more than 50 percent and being forced to leave. Housing activists, such as those at the annual U.S. YIMBY (“Yes in my backyard”) gathering, are challenging city planners and elected officials to create more diverse infill options to house people, stem displacement, make better transit connections, and create more environmentally sustainable communities.

How Did We Get Here?

Desirable cities are growing rapidly because they’re attracting millennials and cultural creatives for job opportunities and lifestyle amenities, and the newcomers have gravitated in numbers that far exceed places to live. The tech industry, with its influxes of well-paid workers, is often blamed for driving up housing costs and causing displacement. But other factors are also in play. Many cities built little if any housing during the Great Recession. Mortgage credit is tighter. Construction costs are escalating. New housing is priced at market rates that drive up the cost for existing homes. Zoning that favors single-family detached houses or luxury apartments has led to expensive housing monocultures. What’s being viewed as a crisis in many cities is the loss of housing not just for lower-income residents but also for workforce and middle-income residents—teachers, nurses, firefighters, small business owners, young professionals, young families, and others who typically provide a foundation for communities.

Restoring the “Missing Middle”

The good news is that cities across the United States are already working on solutions. Communities are overturning policies that prohibit housing or place tight restrictions on where and how it can be built, to allow for more diverse and affordable places to live. Many urban planners and public officials are focused on developing housing types that restore the “missing middle,” to shelter moderate and middle-income households. 

The missing middle, a concept that grew out of new urbanism, includes row houses, duplexes, apartment courts, and other small to midsize housing designed at a scale and density compatible with single-family residential neighborhoods. Since the 1940s, this type of development has been limited by regulatory constraints, the shift to car-dependent development, and incentives for single-family home ownership. Three- or four-story buildings at densities of 16 to 35 dwelling units per acre used to be a standard part of the mix in urban neighborhoods. Many urban planners say this scale and density of housing is needed again to offer diversity, affordability, and walkable access to services and transit. Cities are using a variety of additional approaches to inject more moderately priced housing into residential neighborhoods, from shrinking or subdividing lots to adding accessory dwelling units (ADUs) to expanding legal occupancy in homes. Some of these gentle infill approaches are showing great potential or in fact adding needed units on a faster track. 

How does gentle infill work? It depends on the city, as demonstrated by the following examples from Portland, Oregon; Boulder, Colorado; and Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Portland, Oregon: More Housing is Better

Portland typically ranks atop lists of “best places” to live but has recently slipped a few notches because of its housing prices, which ballooned 13 percent in 2015. According to a recent study released by Metro, the regional government organization, Portland area rents increased 63 percent since 2006, while the average income of renters rose only 39 percent. The population grew by 12,000 in 2015, to more than 632,000 residents in 250,000-plus households. 

Since 1973, Portland has been living with statewide urban planning that mandates an urban growth boundary to protect farmland and forests from urban sprawl and to ensure efficient use of land, public facilities, and services within the urban boundary. This city has an ambitious agenda to meet its growth projections with several big planning efforts: a new zoning map and the 2035 Comprehensive Plan, its first update in 30 years, adopted by city council in June 2016; a new land use code with regulations that affect a range of growth from multifamily and mixed-use development to transportation corridors and parking; and Central City 2035, a long-range development plan for the city center and its districts. 

The city is relying on policy changes in view of the 142,000 additional jobs, 135,000 extra households, and 260,000 more people that it will need to accommodate by 2035, according to Metro. About 30 percent of new housing will be built in the city center, 50 percent in mixed-use centers and corridors, and 20 percent in Portland’s single-family residential zones, which comprise about 45 percent of the city’s 133 square miles of land. The city has about 12,000 buildable lots, assuming that some current lots can be subdivided to provide more sites.

Since 2010, an estimated 20,000 new residential units have been built or are in the pipeline, and tax increment financing in designated urban renewal areas has invested $107 million in new and preserved affordable housing. In 2016, the state legislature lifted a 17-year ban on inclusionary zoning, which will allow the city to require builders to set aside units for new workforce housing. The city is focused on funding strategies to provide more affordable homes for households below 80 percent of the area median income (AMI). To increase the number of middle-income units for people earning more than 80 percent of AMI, the city is relying on policy changes, rather than funding strategies.

By the end of 2016, a stakeholder advisory committee for the Residential Infill Project (RIPSAC) will provide advice regarding the size and scale of houses, small-lot development, and alternative housing types. One proposal under consideration is to allow more internal conversions of large historic houses into multiple units, an approach that would provide more housing while avoiding teardowns and preserving the historic fabric of neighborhoods. Building on the legacy of small homes that exist from a century ago, Portland is looking to add little houses on undersized, pre-platted lots. And the city is considering whether to allow the development of more tall “skinny” homes of up to 1,750 square feet on 2,500 square-foot lots, half the square footage of land required under R-5 single-family zoning.

“Five or ten years ago, people would ask, ‘Why is this house being built on a narrow lot?’” says RIP project manager Morgan Tracy. “Now it’s not so surprising. They’re really becoming popular because they’re at a lower price point for buyers.”

Policy changes regarding accessory dwelling units have helped generate new moderately priced housing and have drawn the attention of public officials from other cities in search of solutions to their own housing crises. ADU construction has exploded since 2010, when the city waived development fees covering sewer, water, and other infrastructure connections, reducing construction costs by $8,000 to $11,000 per unit. The waiver inspired a surge in construction: almost 200 ADUs were permitted in 2013—six times the yearly average from 2000 to 2009. In 2015, the city granted 350 new ADU permits, for a current total of more than 1,500 units. Tracy says ADUs “are a well-accepted means of producing more housing because they’re better integrated into a site and don’t necessitate a home being demolished.”

Any single-family house in the main zoning districts can have an ADU, and a proposal would allow up to two units—an interior apartment plus a separate carriage house or granny flat. The city does not limit the number of ADUs within a neighborhood or require off-street parking. It has also streamlined some ADU standards to allow for improved designs with slightly greater height and setbacks. RIPSAC is considering proposals to allow any house to have two ADUs, both interior and detached, triplexes on corner lots where duplexes are now allowed, and duplexes on interior lots, with a detached ADU. Allowing duplexes on interior lots and triplexes on corners “doesn’t mean everyone will take advantage” of the policy changes, says Tracy, noting that only 3 percent of corners now have duplexes. But “if every property owner took advantage of additional unit potential, we would double the number of housing units in each neighborhood.”

The next phase of infill housing policy considerations will address how medium-density housing types might fit into small infill and multi-dwelling sites. The city has already been moving in that direction: Portland’s Infill Design Toolkit guide focuses on integrating rowhouses, triplexes and fourplexes, courtyard housing, and low-rise multifamily buildings into neighborhoods.

“What may be shocking and alarming for some people becomes more acceptable as you see it more,” says Tracy. “We’re seeing that with duplexes and triplexes in single-family neighborhoods. The last time we built them was in the 1930s and ’40s. We’re trying to promote a wider diversity of housing forms, and some folks are supportive because they understand the need to be able to house more people on available land.”

Boulder: More Housing Is Better, But There Are Down Sides

Boulder is studying what other cities are doing to encourage gentle infill, and a recent trip to Portland by city officials, staff, and business leaders offered perspective on what could work at home. Like Portland, Boulder has determined to halve carbon emissions by 2030, provide more infill housing in the developed city core, protect open space, and encourage public transportation use. But with one-sixth of Portland’s population and different challenges and opportunities, Boulder seeks its own consensus on what gentle infill means.

Located 25 miles northwest of Denver in the foothills of the Rockies, Boulder also ranks high on the lists of healthy, livable, and entrepreneurial places. The natural beauty and high quality of life in this 25.8-square-mile city of 105,000 have attracted start-ups and established tech firms such as Google and Twitter. The influx has fed a digitally paced lifestyle and “1 percent” housing market in which the median single-family detached house costs over $1 million.

In the past two years, housing prices overall have risen 31 percent. Factors beyond the tech industry have limited affordability for many years (disclosure: for nearly 25 years, I’ve lived, worked, and raised two kids in a formerly modest Boulder neighborhood that has been largely rebuilt with higher-end homes). The University of Colorado-Boulder, a key economic driver with 38,000 faculty, staff, and students, generates significant housing demand. A jobs-housing imbalance translates to an estimated 60,000 cars arriving and departing daily, despite regional and local bus service.

State law prohibits rent control, and the state’s “condominium construction defects legislation” has squelched that type of construction for middle-income housing. Boulder is also home to many independently wealthy “trustafarians” and speculative buyers who purchase homes with cash from selling property in other high-end markets. Some are second or third residences; others are reserved for short-term rentals like airbnb. In June 2015, city council voted to restrict short-term vacation rentals, saying they impacted affordability and reduced the number of long-term housing opportunities.

Development limitations include few residential lots, a 45,000-acre ring of protected open space around the city, and a height limit, to preserve mountain views, capped at between 35 and 55 vertical feet, depending on planned development intensity and location near transit. The city is within sight of a theoretical build-out; a forecast of 6,760 additional units by 2040 is being considered for the current update of the Boulder Valley Comprehensive Plan. A 2015 housing survey conducted for the plan indicated that most residents were willing to increase density and building height to allow for more housing, at least in some parts of the city.

Since 1989, while the percentage of lower-income households has held steady, middle-income households have declined from 43 percent to 37 percent of the populace. The segment disappearing at the fastest rate is households earning between $65,000 and $150,000 as well as families with children. City council, the planning board, and local newspaper op-ed pages field lively debates over the “Aspenization” of Boulder and infill housing options that could slow or reverse the city’s momentum toward greater exclusivity and less diversity.

Boulder has been working on affordability and inclusivity for some time. Its inclusionary zoning ordinance produced 3,300 affordable housing units between 2000 and 2016. Developers of projects with five or more units are required to construct 20 percent as permanently affordable, build off-site, donate land, or make a cash-in-lieu payment to the city’s affordable housing fund. The city’s goal is 10 percent permanently affordable housing; some 7.3 percent of the city’s housing stock now qualifies.

Part of the affordable program is aimed at middle-income housing: the city has a goal of creating 450 permanently affordable units for households earning 80 to 120 percent of AMI. Between 2000 and 2016, 107 units for middle-income households were built in new mixed-income neighborhoods on land annexed in north Boulder. Many are in the Holiday neighborhood, a mixed-use model of 42 percent affordable units integrated within a total of 333 townhomes, row houses, flats, live-work studios, and cohousing. Recently built middle-income units are located in the Northfield Commons neighborhood, where half of the 43 percent of affordable units in duplexes, fourplexes, sixplexes, and townhomes are reserved for middle-income households.

“It’s very expensive to subsidize people making $70,000 to $130,000 per year,” says Aaron Brockett, a city council member and former planning board member, referencing a middle-income housing study prepared for the city that defined Boulder’s middle market as 80 to 150 percent of AMI. He advocates for “market solutions like smaller units as a trade-off in those areas that have amenities and services such as mixed-use areas where people can walk to transit and redeveloping areas.”

In preparing a comprehensive housing strategy, Boulder is exploring ideas for middle-income infill housing in transit corridors, commercial strips, business parks, and industrial areas that could be rezoned and redeveloped, and in walkable mixed-use neighborhood centers in residential areas. “The 15-minute neighborhood is the Holy Grail for a lot of communities, but it takes a lot of work,” says Jay Sugnet, project manager for Housing Boulder. “Are they in single-family neighborhoods or at the edge of service-industrial areas? Where are you willing to locate those, and what’s appropriate? You also need a concentration of people to support retail. Boulder has lots of commercial corridors, but they need a sufficient number of people to support all of them.”

The city also plans to adjust the ADU ordinance to achieve more middle-income affordability in neighborhoods of mostly single-family detached houses, which comprise about 41 percent of the city’s 46,000-unit housing stock. An ADU ordinance in effect since 1981 has permitted only 186 ADUs and 42 OAUs (owner’s accessory units) because of requirements regarding off-street parking, minimum lot size, and limits on ADU density. “We’d like ADUs for diversity of housing in neighborhoods,” says David Driskell, executive director of planning, housing, and sustainability. “Physically we could put in quite a few here, but, politically, there will be quite a lot of discussion about parking and traffic impacts.”

City council is considering “creative adjustments” to existing housing that could have less impact on the footprint and “character” of residential areas, such as loosening code restrictions on the number of unrelated people who can share a home. In most residential zones, no more than three unrelated people can share a house, even if it has six bedrooms and multiple bathrooms. A ballot measure petition launched recently by University of Colorado graduate students asks Boulder voters to overturn the occupancy limit and adopt a “one person = one bedroom” policy. Allowing higher occupancy is controversial. Although it would provide more places for students and others to live legally, it could further drive up housing costs for families, as monthly rent in group houses, particularly close to the university, often costs as much as $1,000 per bedroom.

The city is also discussing a revision of its 20-year-old cooperative housing ordinance. No co-op projects have been permitted because the ordinance was “essentially a path to No,” says Driskell. Three affordable rental co-ops were established under other measures. City council is considering a more welcoming ordinance that supporters say would benefit the city by offering a sustainable and community-oriented lifestyle for single residents, young families, seniors, and people who work lower-wage jobs.

“We tend to be a regulatory city, and we have really embraced deliberative planning,” says Susan Richstone, deputy director of planning, housing, and sustainability. “It hasn’t always been easy, but we’re having the discussions and making changes in planning and zoning levels within a regulatory framework. It’s in our DNA.”

“Density is a bogeyman here, and people are up in arms,” says Bryan Bowen, an architect and planner who is a member of the Boulder Planning Board and the city’s Middle Income Working Group.  Residents are anxious about both modest homes being scrapped and replaced with 5,000 square-foot $1.5 million new homes and the possibility of greater density with more large edgy-looking multifamily apartment buildings. “That’s probably why gentle infill feels good, though it has an interpretive quality. It’s a question of what people find to be compatible and palatable.” There’s no consensus yet about which infill approach will work best, Bowen says. “But frankly, in moderation, some application of all of them might be needed.”

 


 

Accessory Dwelling Units (ADUs): A Preferred Infill Housing Approach

Demographic changes such as aging populations, shrinking household size, college-loan-strapped millennials, and cultural preferences are leading many cities to allow home owners to build ADUs, also known as in-law apartments, granny flats, and carriage houses. Advocates say ADUs—built in the interior of a home, rebuilt from a garage, or newly built as a separate cottage—offer affordable options for elderly parents, adult kids, and caregivers. They’re also a source of rental income that can help residents stay in their homes. As older home owners wish to downsize and age in place, some are choosing to live in the ADU and rent out their main house.

Typically ranging from 200 square feet to more than 1,000 square feet, ADUs are part of a long tradition of modest apartments and multigenerational houses that were common before the era of single-family suburban homes. Many housing advocates are keen on ADUs as a way to add units quickly, with home owners financing the infill of existing neighborhoods, compared to the lengthy and costly process of land acquisition and development of larger-scale multifamily projects by municipalities, nonprofit affordable housing organizations, and private developers. At Denver’s Bridging the Gap housing summit in May, a session on small-scale affordability posed a potential scenario for the city: 70 neighborhoods multiplied by 300 ADUs per neighborhood would equal 21,000 moderately priced housing units.

At the 2015 YIMBY conference in Boulder, Susan Somers of AURA (formerly Austinites for Urban Rail Action) in Austin, Texas, described a coalition effort to become “an ADU city” and achieve much greater housing density in the mostly single-family detached city. They accomplished their mission; in November 2015, the Austin City Council passed a resolution relaxing ADU regulations and allowing them on smaller lots. AURA hopes to help home owners entitle 500 new ADUs annually. The units provide “affordable housing and a source of income to allow folks to stay in their homes,” says Somers. In gentrifying East Austin, “this is how families stay together.”

 


 

Cambridge: Bridging the Income Gap

Cambridge, located across the Charles River and three miles west of Boston, has the most expensive housing in Massachusetts and bears keen pressure to produce more missing-middle options. The population has increased more than 10 percent since 2000, to 110,000 residents within a compact 6.5 square miles, and is projected to grow by 6,200 homes before 2030, according to the Metropolitan Area Planning Council (MAPC), the regional planning agency for Metro Boston. The city has 117,000 jobs and more than 52,000 housing units, about half of them located in mixed-use commercial areas. The average listed single-family home price in 2015 exceeded $1.2 million. Median monthly rent for a one-bedroom apartment was $2,300.

“Cambridge has become a bifurcated place of very high income and very low income,” says Andre Leroux, executive director of the Massachusetts Smart Growth Alliance. “It’s hard for middle-class people to live there.” Cambridge has the infrastructure to support much greater density and to add significantly more residential development and huge residential towers, “but it doesn’t want to be downtown Boston.”

The city is in the first year of a three-year comprehensive plan process, its first since 2000 (the state does not require municipalities to develop comprehensive plans). Affordable housing for low, moderate, and middle incomes—a resounding theme through the public process—is the number-one priority, says Iram Farooq, assistant city manager for community development.

“For a lot of working people, there are fewer affordable options in the city,” says Farooq. The greatest population decline has occurred among residents earning between 50 and 80 percent of AMI, she says. Middle-income households earning between 80 and 120 percent of the area’s AMI are also leaving the city for housing options elsewhere in the urban region. She notes that a city program that offered low-interest financing to home buyers earning up to 120 percent of AMI experienced little demand.

“Just creating the program doesn’t mean people are going to use it. With the same financial commitment, they are able to go three miles down the road and find a nicer or bigger house for the same money. Being able to hold onto the middle is more challenging than at other income levels.”

The city is using regulatory strategies to fund more affordable housing. An incentive zoning ordinance enacted in 1988 required linkage payments to offset the effects of commercial development on the housing market. In 2015, the city updated the ordinance, increasing the rate for developers from $4.58 to $12 per square foot and broadening the requirement to include any nonresidential development, including healthcare and university facilities, labs, and office space. The city is also considering new zoning for infill sites and an expansion of its inclusionary housing ordinance, which now requires 11.5 percent affordability in new projects, to 20 percent affordable units for moderate, middle-income, and low-income households.

Cambridge has been building infill housing, mostly in projects ranging from 50 to 300 units, on larger sites. East Cambridge, for example, has seen the development of thousands of housing units in the past decade, along with millions of square feet of office space and restaurants, on land that was formerly industrial. The city is requiring residential units with all new development; 40 percent of a new commercial project in East Cambridge’s Kendall Square will be dedicated to housing. Some of this new development is subsidized for the middle class. But few parcels exist in residential areas, land costs are high, and residents are pushing back.

For years, housing advocates have been urging the city to add more infill housing and increase density in Central Square, the historic municipal center of the city. Located on Massachusetts Avenue, Central Square has a subway station and a bus-transfer station where eight bus routes converge. The area has some three- and four-story buildings as well as one- and two-story buildings that could be redeveloped for dense mixed-use housing next to transit. The square historically had taller, denser buildings before some third and fourth stories were removed to reduce taxes during the Depression. In 2012, however, some neighbors tried to persuade the city to downzone Central Square.

“Downzoning is not appropriate in a crisis in which we’re so restricted in our ability to build housing,” says Jesse Kanshoun-Benanav, an urban planner and affordable housing developer who started the civic group A Better Cambridge in response to the downzoning effort, to promote increased density for infill housing opportunities. The city council tabled the downzoning effort and since then has been allowing zoning changes in Central Square and providing incentives such as additional height and density in exchange for the development of more affordable housing.

At the eastern end of Central Square, Twining Properties is developing Mass + Main, a multiparcel mixed-use project with a 195-foot tower and 270 apartments, 20 percent of which will be affordable for low, moderate, and middle-income residents. The project required a zoning variance, notes Farooq. “We’re now hearing political desire to rezone the rest of Central Square. People don’t seem to be as opposed to density as height, so we’ll have to explore what that means in terms of urban form.”

Townhouses, duplexes, and triple deckers are the norm in Cambridge, and only 7.5 percent are single-family detached homes. New rules passed in May that allow the conversion of basements into accessory dwelling units in single- and two-family homes throughout the city could enable 1,000 legal ADUs. The ADUs don’t need a zoning variance, and off-street parking is not required. The square footage of the new units won’t count as gross floor area (ADUs previously were prohibited in most cases due to the existing floor-area ratio and requirements for lot area per dwelling unit). Supporters say the rules won favor because they allow for more efficient use of large homes and won’t alter the look of the neighborhood.

“It’s important that there are people in the city who are willing to accept trade-offs,” says Farooq, noting that the YIMBY movement has “great political capital” to counter NIMBY pushback against infill housing. “There is a community desire to see more housing, and many young people, including a lot of renters, recognize that it’s important to increase the supply and not have steep increases in rent, to make housing more manageable and accessible.”

Regional Approaches

Leroux from the Massachusetts Smart Growth Alliance and others across the nation say that housing needs should be addressed as a regional issue, and cities and towns should work together to allow urban infill housing and approaches like ADUs under state zoning laws. In June, the Massachusetts Senate passed a bill that would reform 1970s-era zoning laws to permit ADUs and multifamily housing districts in every community. A coalition including the Alliance; the Senate President; mayors; and advocates for the environment, public health, affordable housing, and transportation supported the bill, which is poised to become state law next legislative session. A legal and policy strategy, it includes a fair-housing clause that prohibits communities from making discriminatory land-use decisions, which Leroux and others say increase segregation in many metropolitan areas, as low-income residents, including people of color, get pushed out of redeveloping urban neighborhoods.

Suburban communities also need to do their fair share, he says. Many suburbs are still zoning and building for the auto-oriented market, with “a lot of modest homes being torn down and replaced with McMansions,” he says. “We think there’s a grand bargain to be made between cities and towns and the real estate development community to unshackle development near walkable places, infrastructure, and transportation while curbing sprawl and protecting natural areas.” To allow for more diverse housing growth, he says, the Alliance and others are promoting “as-of-right,” or permitted zoning uses, in walkable areas, commercial centers, villages, town centers, and urban squares, because “that’s where the market is and where we need to let the market do its job.”

This article originally appeared in July 2016 Land Lines.

 


 

Kathleen McCormick, principal of Fountainhead Communications, LLC, lives and works in Boulder, Colorado, and writes frequently about sustainable, healthy, and resilient communities.

Photograph: Fred King

The latest manufactured homes

From Stigma to Housing Fix

The Evolution of Manufactured Homes
By Loren Berlin, Enero 25, 2018

Liz Wood wanted to buy a house. It was 2006, she had been renting for A decade, and her monthly payments were getting high. She was 43 and steadily employed, earning $34,000 annually plus benefits as a family educator. She didn’t want anything fancy, just a place where she could “gather love and bring stability.” She would stay within her means.

Nonetheless, the math was tricky. Wood lives in Duvall, Washington, a town of roughly 7,500 in the foothills of the Cascade Mountains. Steeped in lush forest, Duvall is about 30 miles from Seattle and a mere eight miles from the City of Redmond, the headquarters for Microsoft. The median income in Duvall is nearly twice that of the state of Washington, and homes in this area are expensive. In 2010, the median value of owner-occupied homes in Duvall was $373,500, compared to $262,100 for the state, according to the U.S. Census Bureau.

With few options, Wood eventually decided on manufactured housing. For $55,000, she purchased a used factory-built home in Duvall Riverside Village, a four-acre community of 25 manufactured homes in the middle of downtown Duvall. “It’s amazing here,” she says. “I live on riverfront property, so when I walk out my door I see water, pine trees, and a walking trail that goes from my house to the next town. I wake up in the morning hearing birds. I know all my neighbors. I’m connected to my community. I’m a block from the police station. I feel safe.”

But it was still difficult. Wood owned her house, but not the land on which it sits. Instead, she rented the plot for $450 a month, plus water and utilities, as did the other residents of Duvall Riverside Village. As a result, Wood and her neighbors remained largely at the mercy of the property owner, their landlord, and forfeited much of the autonomy and security associated with more traditional home ownership models.

Their landlord prohibited garages, leaving residents limited storage options. He charged them $25 a month per additional car or adult beyond those registered at the time of move-in. He charged $5 a month for every pet and required dogs to be leashed at all times. There was a $5 monthly fee for every extra half-cord of firewood, which Wood needed to fuel her stove. Though he employed a groundskeeper, he didn’t install outdoor lights, nor did he maintain the community roads, which were pocked and cracked.

In 2012, Wood and her neighbors received a written notice that the owner was selling the land. Unlike many owners, who prefer to sell their properties to a developer, this landlord was open to selling to residents. He had agreed to host a meeting with the tenants, a real estate broker, and the Northwest Cooperative Development Center, a nonprofit that supports cooperatives. The parties discussed the possibility of establishing a nonprofit, resident-owned cooperative to purchase the property. In doing so, they would conserve the land for manufactured housing, continue living there as a community, and collectively manage it to guarantee a safe, affordable, high-quality experience.

The residents voted to go for it. The landlord had two demands. He wanted fair market value, and he wanted to complete the sale by the end of the year. It was already August. They had five months.

In addition to the collaboration with Northwest Cooperative Development Center, the residents also began working with ROC USA, a New Hampshire–based nonprofit organization that offers residents of manufactured housing communities a mix of technical assistance and affordable financing to purchase their rented land when it becomes available for sale. Between its establishment in 2008 and 2016, ROC USA has successfully facilitated 80 of these transactions nationally and secured more than $175 million in financing for them.

ROC USA works with a network of eight regional affiliates, including the Northwest Cooperative Development Center. In Duvall, the nonprofits worked together with the residents to assess the economics of a possible deal and to confirm that the community was a good fit for resident ownership. Next, the organizations helped the residents to hire a third-party lawyer and establish their cooperative, which would operate as a democracy with residents elected into leadership positions by fellow residents. ROC USA assisted the residents to hire an independent engineer and conduct due diligence of the property; secure financing through ROC USA’s lending subsidiary, ROC USA Capital, to purchase the property and undertake critical repairs; and organize the real estate transfer.

On December 27 of that year, the newly formed cooperative bought the Duvall Riverside Village with $1.3 million in purchase financing from ROC USA Capital, granting Wood and her fellow home owners control over their living arrangements, and permanently preserving 25 affordable homes in a town where such housing stock is scarce.

The residents continue to pay $450 a month to rent the land, but now they vote to determine community rules, and use the rent to make improvements and to pay the community’s mortgage, taxes, and expenses.

“Now, you can have a garage if you want,” explains Wood, who is president of the Duvall residents’ cooperative and a ROC USA board member. “And we spent $35,000 to fix the roads. We don’t have to live in fear anymore, so people are willing to invest in their homes. We have annual meetings to vote in projects. We can lower the monthly rent if we are over-budgeting for things we don’t need. The bottom line is that we are in control of our own destiny.”

Upon completing the sale, ROC USA and the Northwest Cooperative Development Center have continued providing the residents with technical support to ensure smooth operations.

“If they had just lent us the money and said, ‘these are the guidelines, here’s what you need to do, have at it,’ we would have failed,” explains Wood. “But they are an ongoing resource. They help us with tough situations, or when we don’t know how to do something legally. The goal is for us to become independent and to be able to run our community like a business. Pay your bills, and your house can stay where it is. Period. Forever.”

Benefits

Across the United States, more than 18 million Americans live in factory-built homes, which represent 5 percent of the nation’s housing stock in metro areas, and 15 percent in rural communities as of 2015. They range significantly in quality.  Roughly 25 percent of today’s manufactured housing stock is the stereotyped, rickety trailers from the 1960s and early 1970s, produced before the federal government introduced quality controls in 1976. The remaining 75 percent complies with the federal standards and includes charming, energy-efficient homes, indistinguishable to the untrained eye from their site-built counterparts. Though manufactured homes have long been cast aside as a housing choice of last resort, today’s models are robust, efficient, and inviting, with the potential to help alleviate the nation’s shortage of safe, affordable housing.

Modern manufactured homes cost approximately half as much as their site-built counterparts and can be built five times faster, making them a genuinely viable option for low-income consumers. The production process is less wasteful, and models that comply with the federal government’s Energy Star standards offer home owners meaningful energy savings. And they are durable. Whereas manufactured homes built prior to the 1976 regulations were made to be portable, like recreational vehicles, modern models are built with stronger materials and designed to be permanent. Today’s manufactured homes can sit on any foundation that would otherwise accommodate a site-built structure, creating the flexibility to use the housing in a wide range of geographies and environments.

“The manufactured housing stock is a critical component of the nation’s affordable housing,” says George McCarthy, president and CEO of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. “It easily outnumbers our subsidized stock two or three times in almost every market.”

Manufactured homes are cheaper to produce than site-built houses because of the manufacturing process. As Andrea Levere, president of the Corporation for Enterprise Development, wrote in the Huffington Post, the “term ‘manufactured housing’ itself has less to do with quality and more to do with the production process, which is a derivative of Ford’s assembly lines. This model allows manufactured homes to be built in a more controlled work environment, translating into predictable costs, increased efficiencies, and reduced waste” (Levere 2013).

In 2013, a new, energy-efficient manufactured home cost $64,000, compared to $324,500 for a new, site-built one, according to the U.S. Census, though the price for the latter includes the land. Even after stripping out the land costs, manufactured homes are still significantly less expensive, averaging $44 per square foot, versus $94 per square foot for site-built homes. And they are unsubsidized, which is a boon given the extremely short supply of subsidized housing compared to demand. Only one in four income-qualified families receives a housing subsidy, according to the Bipartisan Policy Commission, leaving the remaining 75 percent in need of an affordable, unsubsidized alternative. By helping to fill that gap, manufactured housing can relieve some of the demand for subsidized housing that state and federal governments are struggling to supply in the face of shrinking budgets. “The majority of families who live in manufactured housing would qualify for subsidized housing, but instead they choose this less expensive and unsubsidized option,” says McCarthy.

The stock is also very versatile, argues McCarthy, who cites its role in housing people during the immediate aftermath of Hurricane Sandy. “Recovery workers got 17 manufactured homes on the ground in New Jersey within weeks of the hurricane—permanent homes for displaced renters, not the problematic ‘Katrina trailers.’ And they did it before most organizations even had a housing plan. This speaks to the efficiency and nimbleness of building manufactured housing. The production times are about 80 percent shorter than for site-built homes, making them the best housing option for disaster response.”

Nevertheless, manufactured housing often gets a bad rap, due largely to the widespread misperception that today’s models are the same as the earliest generations of mobile homes built prior to the introduction of quality control standards by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development in 1976. Today, there are roughly 2 million of these pre-1976 homes; many are barely hanging together and house the nation’s most vulnerable populations, including the elderly and disabled. Though the pre-1976 stock is virtually unrelated to its present-day counterpart, these older, dilapidated dwellings dominate the general public perception of manufactured homes in the United States.

The housing stock’s reputation is further diminished by the vulnerabilities facing home owners who do not own the land on which they live. Roughly 3 million people live in one of the nation’s 50,000 manufactured housing communities, while another 3 million rent on private property. There are manufactured housing communities in every state in the country. Like Duvall Riverside Village, many of them are on prime real estate, and the landowners routinely receive purchase offers from developers.

Advocates working to improve the manufactured home ownership experience, and to promote the stock’s viability as affordable housing, are focusing on three critical areas of innovation: conserving mobile-home parks; replacing pre-1976 units with modern, energy-efficient homes; and increasing access to affordable financing, which is virtually unavailable for potential buyers in the current market, and is imperative to building equity and preserving a home’s resale value.

Conserving Manufactured Housing Communities

The conversion of Duvall Riverside Village from a privately owned mobile home community to a resident-owned cooperative is not common. For every community available for purchase that is successfully preserved as affordable housing, there are many more that end up sold for redevelopment, displacing residents who may lack good alternatives.

“It’s not as simple as just moving the home,” says Ishbel Dickens, president of the National Manufactured Home Owners Association. “First, there’s the question of whether the home can even be moved. It may be too old or unstable to survive a move. And even if it can be moved, it’s expensive to do so, and very hard to find a space in another community. In most instances, when a park closes, the residents are probably going to lose the home and all their equity in it.  In all likelihood, they will never own a home again. They’ll likely end up on a wait list for subsidized housing, or may even end up homeless.”

To some degree, it’s an accident of history that so many of today’s mobile home parks occupy plots of coveted real estate, says Paul Bradley, president of ROC USA. As he explains it, in the late 1950s and 1960s, Americans began to embrace transportable trailers and campers, in part because of a cultural shift toward outdoor recreation, and in part because post–World War II factories began producing them to utilize excess manufacturing capacity, making them widely available and affordable. As the units grew in popularity, they transitioned from temporary structures to permanent ones, and people began adding makeshift carports and sunrooms. At the time, urban planners accepted the evolution toward permanency. As they saw it, most of the trailers were on land that no one else was using in outer-circle developments. Why not let these campers stay for awhile, until the cities expanded to meet them, at which point the land would be redeveloped?

“These original communities were built with a plan to close them,” says Bradley. “Back then, no one contemplated the full implications of creating a housing stock for which home owners lacked control of the underlying land. No one anticipated that these communities would be full of low- and moderate-income home owners who spent their own money to buy these homes and had few alternatives. And that’s what we are still grappling with today. That lack of control over the land means that home owners live with a deep sense of insecurity and the feeling that it’s irrational to make investments in their properties because they won’t get it back. What’s the implication for home owners who cannot rationally argue for investing in their home? What does that mean for the housing stock? For neighborhoods?”

Short-sighted land use policies are not the only challenge to preserving manufactured housing communities. An equally onerous obstacle is the lack of legal protections afforded to residents. In 34 states and the District of Columbia, the landowner can sell the property without giving residents the opportunity to purchase it. In fact, in most states, the landowner doesn’t have to notify residents that the community is for sale; the landowner can wait until the property has been sold to inform residents of the transaction, suddenly leaving them in a tenuous position. Even the 16 states that require the owner of a manufactured housing community to provide residents advance notice of a sale do not necessarily afford tenants the necessary protections. “In most of the states with advance notice, there are so many limitations on the notice requirements that it is rarely of any use to residents,” says Carolyn Carter, director of advocacy at the National Consumer Law Center.

To better protect residents, advocates support legislative reforms to state laws and tax incentives for landowners who sell to residents. The most effective of these strategies are state laws requiring a landowner to give residents both advance notice of the sale—ideally 60 days—and the opportunity to purchase the property, argues Carter. According to her, six states have laws that “work on the ground and provide effective opportunities for residents to purchase their communities,” including New Hampshire, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Florida, Vermont, and Delaware. She says Oregon passed promising legislation in January 2015.

“In those states with effective notice and opportunity to purchase laws, resident ownership takes off,” Carter explains. Roughly 46 percent of the 80 communities that ROC USA supports are in either New Hampshire or Massachusetts—two small states with some of the nation’s strongest resident protections. There are 89 additional resident-owned cooperatives in New Hampshire that predate ROC USA’s launch.

To understand the value of strong consumer laws for residents, consider the story of Ryder Woods, a 174-unit mobile home park in Milford, Connecticut, 11 miles south of New Haven, just off a major thoroughfare. Connecticut is one of 19 states that either offer tax incentives or provide residents “some” protections when a community is sold, but also contain “significant gaps,” according to Carter.

In 1998, Ryder Woods’ landowner sold the property to developers. He informed the residents via eviction notices, in violation of state laws requiring him both to give them advance notice of the pending sale and to provide them the right of first refusal to purchase the land. Ryder Woods had an active home owners association, and very quickly they organized protests and petitions and lobbied the state legislature to reverse the sale. Eventually, the local news picked up their story, at which point a Milford-based attorney volunteered her services to help them. As she dug into the case, she realized that the law was on the side of the residents and that the community needed more legal support than she alone could offer. She enlisted help from a friend and fellow attorney—a partner at a prominent, Hartford-based firm—who agreed to take the case pro bono and assigned it a team of attorneys. The case ended up going to trial, eventually making its way to the state’s highest court. Uninterested in the unfolding legal headache, the original buyer resold the property to a second developer.

Four years after the original sale, the courts ruled in favor of the residents. In an unprecedented deal, and as required as part of the settlement, the second developer purchased a new piece of land a mile from the original parcel and completely rebuilt the community there. The developer purchased 174 new mobile homes and sold them to the residents at significantly reduced prices with more favorable mortgage terms than any available in the conventional financing market. He built a community center and a pond, complete with swans. And, as required by their agreement, he provided the residents the opportunity to form a cooperative and buy the land, which they did in 2009 with $5.4 million in purchase financing from ROC USA Capital. They closed on their purchase in the offices of the Hartford firm, which had continued to volunteer its services to the residents through the sale’s completion. Today, there is a Walmart on the land that housed the original Ryder Woods community.

“Sometimes, when we look back, we think it was crazy. We chartered a bus, went to Hartford, spoke to the legislature, and just fought it. We stuck together and won against two big-time, billion-dollar developers,” explains Lynn Nugent, 68, a part-time merchandise associate at Sears, and one of the residents who helped organize the campaign, along with her husband, a retired locksmith. “Now I always say, ‘Somebody else used to own us, and now we own ourselves.’”

Improving Access to Quality, Affordable Manufactured Homes

Unlike the residents of Ryder Woods, many owners of manufactured homes struggle to secure a quality unit with affordable financing. Here again, legislation is a primary culprit. Under federal law, manufactured homes are considered personal property, like a car or a boat, opposed to the real property designation assigned to traditional homes. Consequently, buyers cannot access mortgage loans. Instead, financing is available in the form of personal “chattel” loans. More expensive than mortgage loans, they average an additional 50 to 500 basis points and provide fewer consumer protections. More than 70 percent of purchase loans for manufactured homes are these higher-cost loans, which are considered a proxy for subprime products.  

“This second-tier status is one of the biggest limitations to increasing the stock of permanently affordable manufactured homes,” says McCarthy. “It makes financing the homes more challenging and expensive than it should be, and it diminishes the homes’ wealth-building potential because it reduces effective demand for existing units.”

While the dream fix would be to change federal titling laws, such revisions are not forthcoming. Instead, Next Step, a Kentucky-based nonprofit organization, has established “Manufactured Housing Done Right (MHDR).” This innovative strategy works to make high-quality, affordable manufactured homes—and financing—available to low- and moderate-income consumers through a combination of energy-efficient houses, home buyer education, and affordable financing.

First, Next Step gives low-income buyers access to high-quality manufactured homes. The organization created a portfolio of models that are both robust and affordable. Each Next Step home meets or exceeds Energy Star standards, reducing utility costs for the home owner and shrinking the environmental footprint. According to Next Step, testing has shown these homes to be 30 percent more efficient than a baseline code home and 10 to 15 percent more efficient than a baseline Energy Star home. On average, this results in $1,800 in energy savings each year for every pre-1976 mobile home replacement and $360 each year for every new home placement.

Additionally, Next Step homes are “value engineered to ensure affordability while upholding quality standards.” They are installed on permanent foundations, providing for greater structural support against wind and reducing settling issues. The homes contain high-quality flooring and insulation, which help to increase durability and reduce energy costs. And because water is the number one problem for foundations, Next Step homes contain additional safeguards to protect against moisture.

Improving Access to Sustainable Financing

Next Step also makes sure the home buyers can secure sustainable, affordable financing. “One of the problems facing the industry is that the capital markets don’t participate in a big way,” explains Stacey Epperson, CEO of Next Step. “The secondary market is not there in any meaningful way, so there are very few lenders in this marketplace and very few options for buyers. Our solution is to prepare our borrowers for home ownership, and then bring them good loans.”

Next Step works with a mix of nonprofit and for-profit lenders, vetted by the organization, to provide safe, reasonably priced financing. In return, Next Step reduces the lenders’ risk. The homes are designed to meet the lenders’ requirements, and the home buyers receive comprehensive financial education so that they are equipped to succeed as home buyers. Consequently, Next Step home buyers not only secure a better initial mortgage, but also have the capacity to build equity and obtain a good resale price for the home should they decide to sell it one day.

Importantly, each Next Step home is placed on a permanent foundation in order to qualify the home owner for certain government-backed mortgage programs, which are less expensive than a chattel product. Next Step estimates it has saved its 173 home buyers approximately $16.1 million in interest payments as of 2015.

“Close to 75 percent of all financing for manufactured housing is going out as chattel. But 70 percent of new manufactured homes are going out on private land where, in many cases, the home could be put on a permanent foundation, and the owner could get a mortgage with a lower interest rate and a longer term,” says Epperson.

The MHDR model is innovative in part because it is scalable. Next Step trains and relies on a membership network of nonprofit organizations to implement the model in their respective communities. Next Step sells the homes to members at competitive prices, and then member organizations oversee the process of identifying and educating buyers, assisting them to secure the loan, and managing the installation.

“The way the industry works, there has never really been a way for a nonprofit to buy a manufactured home at wholesale prices. That’s what we’ve engineered, and that’s what makes these homes a lot more affordable than if the nonprofit or home owner tried to buy them on their own,” explains Kevin Clayton, president and CEO of Clayton Homes, one of the nation’s largest producers of manufactured housing, and one of Next Step’s long-time supporters.

“The Next Step program works because it sets people up for success,” says Clayton. “Next Step takes them through home ownership counseling, and supports home owners if they have a hardship down the road. They get to buy the house for a lot less than they otherwise could have, build equity in the home, and have a low monthly loan payment and energy costs.”

Cyndee Curtis, a Next Step home owner, agrees. Curtis was 27, single, and pregnant when she purchased a used, 1971 Fleetwood mobile home for $5,000 in 2001. She put it on the lot she owned just outside the town of Great Falls, Montana.

“I didn’t have money, I didn’t have a degree, and I didn’t have choices,” says Curtis. “The old steel septic tank was a ticking time bomb, with rust holes. The carpet was worn through, the linoleum underneath had burn spots on it, and the ceiling leaked where an addition had been added. Every year, I would buy construction books, go to Home Depot, and ask how to fix that leak. And every year I ended up there by myself, trying to fix it. There was mold on the doorway from that leak, and I had a newborn in there.”

In 2005, Curtis went back to school for two years, obtained her nursing degree, and began working as a licensed practical nurse, earning $28,500 a year. “I figured now I am earning a livable wage and can explore my options,” says the single mother of two. “I wanted something that my kids could grow up in and be proud of, and to make the most of owning the lot I lived on.”

But her credit was poor, and eventually she ended up at NeighborWorks Montana, a nonprofit Next Step Network member that told her about the Next Step program. Over the next two and a half years, Curtis worked with the staff of NeighborWorks Montana to repair her credit. With their assistance, she secured a mortgage and purchased a Next Step home for $102,000, which included not only the house but also the removal, disposal, and replacement of her old septic system.  Because the Next Step home is on a permanent foundation that meets certain qualifications—and because of Curtis’s improved credit history, income, and geography—she qualified for a mortgage from the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s Rural Development program, which was significantly less expensive than the more common chattel products. Additionally, whereas Curtis’s previous mobile home was titled like a car, her Next Step home is deeded like a site-built house. Consequently, a future buyer will also be eligible to apply for a traditional mortgage.

Curtis says her Next Step home has provided her significant energy savings. “I have 400 square feet more now than I had previously. I went from having one bathroom to two. And still both my gas and power bills have been cut by about two-thirds.”

She continues. “My house is a thousand percent better than what I lived in before. If a person goes inside my house, they can’t tell it’s a manufactured home. It has nice doorways, nice walls that are textured. It looks like any new home you would want to live in.”

“Sometimes people think they have to suffer with poor housing conditions. I know how it is, and I want them to know that if you put in some hard work,  you can make a difference for yourself and your family.”

This article originally appeared in July 2015 Land Lines.

 


 

Loren Berlin is a writer and communications consultant based in Greater Chicago. She can be reached at loren@lorenberlin.com.

 


 

References

Levere, Andrea. 2013. “Hurricane Sandy and the Merits of Manufactured Housing.” Huffington Post. January 8. http://www.huffingtonpost.com/andrea-leverehurricane-sandy-manufactured-housing_b_2426797.html

Photograph of George W. McCarthy

Message from the President

Protecting a Share of the Housing Market
By George W. McCarthy, Enero 25, 2018

People who work with me are often surprised by the extent to which my philosophical canon derives from low-budget offbeat films, typically from the 1980s. When in need of wisdom, I frequently turn to the teachings of Repo Man or, for this essay, Terry Gilliam’s allegorical masterpiece Time Bandits. In the movie, a group of public workers are employed by the Supreme Being to fill holes in the time-space continuum left from the haste of creating the universe in seven days: “It was a bit of a botched job, you see.”

Like the Time Bandits, policy makers are often tasked to fill holes—actual potholes in roadways, or more theoretical holes that are the artifacts of dysfunctional private markets, such as the inadequate supply of affordable housing. For example, housing economists in the United States have become quite adept at tracking the size of the hole, which has only become harder to fill since the federal government committed to address it as a national policy priority beginning with the Housing Act of 1949, part of President Harry S. Truman’s Fair Deal.

In his 1949 State of the Union address, President Truman noted that to fill the needs of millions of families with inadequate housing, “Most of the houses we need will have to be built by private enterprise, without public subsidy.” Nearly 70 years later, our collective failure to solve the affordable housing deficit may stem from wrongheaded analysis of the problem, and the conclusion that market-based solutions can be designed to solve the mismatch between the supply of affordable housing and demand for it.

To support this claim, permit me a short departure into market theory. From the now-preferred mathematical approach to economic analysis, a market is simply a system of partial differential equations that is solved by a single price. The equations capture the complex decisions made by consumers and producers of goods—reconciling consumers’ preferences and budgets with producers’ production techniques, capital, and transaction costs—to arrive at a price that clears the market by settling the transactions of all suppliers and consumers willing to trade at that price.

Acclaimed economists Arrow, Debreu, and McKenzie proved the theoretical existence of a single set of prices that can simultaneously solve for the “general equilibrium” of all markets in a national or global economy. One important aspect of this Nobel Prize–winning contribution was the observation that a unique price cleared each market—one market, one price. There was no expectation that a single price could maintain equilibrium in two markets. And this is the fundamental flaw of the housing market—it is actually two markets, not one. Housing markets supply both shelter for local consumption and a globally tradable investment good made possible by broad capital markets that serve global investors. This dual-market status used to pertain to owner-occupied housing, but, with the proliferation of real estate investment trusts, rental markets are now in the same boat.

Markets for consumption goods behave very differently than investment markets, responding to different “fundamentals.” On the supply side, prices for consumption goods are dictated by production costs, while prices in investment markets are dictated by expected returns. On the demand side, such things as tastes and preferences, household incomes, and demographics determine the price of housing as shelter. Investment demand for housing is dictated by factors like liquidity and liquidity preferences of investors, expected returns on alternative investments, or interest rates.

In developed countries, global capital markets and the market for shelter collide locally with little chance of reconciliation. Local households compete with global investors to decide the character and quantity of housing that is produced. In markets that attract global investment, plenty of housing is produced, but shortages of affordable units are acute, and worsen over time. This is because a huge share of new housing is produced to maximize investment return, not to meet the needs of the local population for shelter. For example, there is no shortage of global investment willing to participate in developing $100 million apartments in New York City. But affordable housing, being much harder to finance, is in short supply. And in markets that have been abandoned by global capital, house prices fall below production costs, and surplus housing accumulates and decays. In extreme cases such as Detroit, market order can only be restored by demolishing thousands of abandoned homes and buildings.

Perhaps it is time that we question the conclusion that market-based solutions can address the challenge of sheltering a country’s population. Truman concluded that “By producing too few rental units and too large a proportion of high-priced houses, the building industry is rapidly pricing itself out of the market.” But Truman was thinking about the market for shelter, not investment. Remarkably, the number of housing units in developed countries significantly exceeds the number of households. In 2016, the U.S. Census estimated that there were 135 million units of housing in the country and 118 million households. One in seven housing units was vacant. This over-supply of housing characterizes every metropolitan market in the United States—even markets with extreme shortages of affordable housing. In 2016, 10.3 percent of housing units were vacant in New York, 6.0 percent in the San Francisco Bay area, 8.2 percent in Washington, DC, and a stunning 13.7 percent in Honolulu. The problem is that many households have insufficient incomes to afford the housing that is available.

In the end, rather than fill the holes in the fabric of time and space, the Time Bandits decided to take advantage of them to “get bloody stinking rich.” The bandits sought to capitalize on celestial imperfections, the way global investors seek returns from short-term market dislocations. To illustrate the dangers of such naked speculation in unregulated markets, consider an apocalyptic tale from a very different market. In 1974, heavy rains during planting season in Bangladesh suggested that rice might be in short supply at harvest time, and rice prices started to rise. Savvy commodity speculators realized that there would be a good return on any rice that was held off the market. The actual harvest produced a bumper crop, but the interaction between market expectations and market manipulations by commodity investors produced one of the worst famines of the 20th century—with an estimated 1.5 million famine-related fatalities. The famine did not result from real food shortages. The collision of the market for goods and the market for speculative investment priced rice out of the reach of the local populations, with landless families suffering mortality at three times the rate of families with land.

Perhaps shelter and food are too important to be left to unregulated markets to allocate. Perhaps public policy should focus on protecting a share of the market—and the public—from the ravages of speculation. In this special anthology issue of Land Lines, Loren Berlin describes efforts to preserve affordable housing in the form of manufactured homes and to promote permanent affordability of that stock through the conversion of manufactured housing communities to limited equity cooperatives. Community land trusts and inclusionary housing policies are also effective ways to insulate shelter from speculation, as demonstrated by Lincoln Institute research. After almost seven decades of failed efforts to get private markets to meet populations’ needs for affordable shelter, it might be time to develop, and to export, these other approaches based on a more realistic understanding of the complexity of housing and capital markets.

This article originally appeared in July 2015 Land Lines.

Curso

Tierra Vacante, Ciudad Compacta y Sustentabilidad

Febrero 17, 2018 - Marzo 13, 2018

Free, offered in español


El curso busca presentar alternativas para el manejo de la tierra vacante en la definición de políticas de suelo. Analiza experiencias concretas de gestión de tierra vacante, problemas en su implementación y el potencial no aprovechado.

Ver la convocatoria


Detalles

Date
Febrero 17, 2018 - Marzo 13, 2018
Application Period
Enero 9, 2018 - Enero 29, 2018
Selection Notification Date
Febrero 9, 2018 at 6:00 PM
Idioma
español
Costo
Free
Registration Fee
Free
Educational Credit Type
Lincoln Institute certificate

Keywords

catastro, mitigación climática, medio ambiente, controles de crecimiento, vivienda, banco de tierras, regulación del mercado de suelo, especulación del suelo, uso de suelo, planificación de uso de suelo, gobierno local, políticas públicas, crecimiento inteligente, urbano, desarrollo urbano, expansión urbana descontrolada

Curso

Alternativas de Gestión del Suelo para la Producción de Vivienda Social

Febrero 17, 2018 - Marzo 13, 2018

Free, offered in español


El curso presenta distintas posibilidades de gestionar el suelo para vivienda de interés social que han sido aplicadas en ciudades de América Latina y, a partir de casos concretos, discute la relación entre políticas nacionales y municipales de vivienda, sus mecanismos financieros y las opciones de movilización de plusvalías.

Ver la convocatoria


Detalles

Date
Febrero 17, 2018 - Marzo 13, 2018
Application Period
Enero 9, 2018 - Enero 29, 2018
Selection Notification Date
Febrero 9, 2018 at 6:00 PM
Idioma
español
Costo
Free
Registration Fee
Free
Educational Credit Type
Lincoln Institute certificate

Keywords

Favela, vivienda, inequidad, mercados informales de suelo, banco de tierras, regulación del mercado de suelo, especulación del suelo, uso de suelo, planificación de uso de suelo, temas legales, pobreza, políticas públicas, reutilización de suelo urbano, barrio bajo, urbano, desarrollo urbano, mejoramiento urbano y regularización

A virtual model shows the line of sight from inside an apartment toward a city skyline

Tasación virtual

Valuación masiva con la ayuda de SIG en Shenzhen
Por Tom Nunlist, Octubre 31, 2017

China es uno de los pocos países del mundo que no cobra impuestos a las propiedades residenciales privadas. Luego de que el Partido Comunista estableciera un régimen socialista en 1949, el país adoptó un sistema de propiedad territorial pública y, por lo tanto, no tuvo un mercado inmobiliario hasta la época de la reforma.

Desde la reforma, se observó un boom de ventas inmobiliarias y de la economía en general. Las ciudades de primer nivel, como Shanghái y Beijing, hoy albergan algunas de las propiedades más caras del mundo. Pero los impuestos se aplican solo en el momento de la venta y las transacciones del inmueble, no de forma anual a los propietarios.

Así, puede sorprender el hecho de que China está a la vanguardia en la evolución de la tecnología de tasación, en particular en Shenzhen, la flamante y nueva ciudad del sur que, desde 1982, creció tanto que pasó de ser un pueblito con 50.000 habitantes a una gran metrópolis con 12 millones. El Centro de tasaciones de Shenzhen, un organismo legal municipal fundado para ayudar en el cobro de impuestos sobre ventas y transacciones de bienes inmuebles, ha desarrollado un sistema de tasación de propiedades que podría ser considerado el más avanzado del mundo. Se trata de una extensión lógica del sistema de valuación masiva asistida por computadora (CAMA, por su sigla en inglés), que se desarrolló para computadoras de escritorio hace décadas y para el cual el Instituto Lincoln tuvo una participación fundamental. El Centro de desarrollo urbano y políticas de suelo de la Universidad de Pekín y el Instituto Lincoln (PLC) ayudó a varias ciudades chinas a implementar CAMA para anticiparse a un futuro impuesto inmobiliario. Lo que distingue al sistema de Shenzhen es el uso de tecnología SIG y nuevas técnicas que llevan a CAMA al siguiente nivel.

Hoy, CAMA es un estándar internacional con el cual se pueden tasar zonas metropolitanas enteras desde una computadora de escritorio. Pero es más que nada un sistema bidimensional por naturaleza, mientras que el software de sistema de información geográfica (SIG) puede crear mapas tridimensionales (3D) con eficiencia. El futuro de la tasación de propiedades recae en la vinculación entre las técnicas de CAMA y las herramientas SIG, en un sistema que, naturalmente, se conoce como “GAMA”.

En general, los sistemas de CAMA no son muy emocionantes a nivel visual: tienen muchas tablas de datos y mapas bidimensionales muy detallados. En comparación, GAMA es deslumbrante. El sistema utiliza las herramientas SIG y construye modelos 3D de ciudades enteras, con calles, edificios, propiedades individuales dentro de ellos, características del paisaje, etcétera. Imagine la sensación de un videojuego de mundo abierto. El objetivo es poder valuar todas las propiedades desde una computadora en la oficina de valuaciones.

“Según mi punto de vista, Shenzhen lleva a CAMA a un nivel superior y hace cosas en las tasaciones que nadie más puede hacer”, dijo George W. McCarthy, presidente y director ejecutivo del Instituto Lincoln.

Shenzhen: centro del progreso

En muchos sentidos, el desarrollo del sistema de tasaciones inmobiliarias de Shenzhen es la historia clásica de la China moderna: comenzó muy atrasado, absorbió conocimientos de economías más avanzadas, los adaptó a las necesidades locales y al final llegó a competir con los mejores del mundo. No es de sorprender que esto haya sucedido en Shenzhen, la Zona Económica Especial donde se lanzó el experimento por el cual China dejó de ser una economía rural y se convirtió en una potencia mundial.

En 1979 China trazaba el curso de la nueva reforma y declaró a cuatro ciudades “Zonas Económicas Especiales (ZEE)”, proyectos piloto en los que el gobierno debía experimentar con los mecanismos del mercado. Shenzhen, un pueblo pesquero con apenas 30.000 habitantes, fue una de ellas. Ubicada junto a Hong Kong, que en ese momento era administrada por los ingleses y estaba muy internacionalizada, Shenzhen contaba con la posición perfecta para cumplir con la misión de las ZEE: atraer el negocio de empresas mundiales, acercar inversiones extranjeras directas y otorgar a China las herramientas necesarias para forjar una nación moderna y desarrollada.

Con la gran cantidad de inversiones y las nuevas fábricas, Shenzhen se convirtió en el corazón de la nueva economía del país y en una de las ciudades más avanzadas del mundo. En apenas tres décadas se convirtió en una metrópolis ajetreada, con casi 12 millones de personas. En 2016, el PIB oficial fue de US$ 284.000 millones (RMB 1,88 billones), con un PIB per cápita de US$ 25.790 (RMB 171.013), más del triple del promedio de China. Se la suele llamar el Silicon Valley de China y alberga algunas de las empresas tecnológicas más poderosas del mundo, entre ellas Tencent, el gigante de Internet.

Ya en 2003, el gobierno central comenzó a pensar en introducir un impuesto a la propiedad. Se seleccionaron seis ciudades como experimentos piloto para hacer una valuación masiva. Shenzhen fue una de ellas. Ese mismo año se fundó el Centro de tasación y desarrollo inmobiliario para empezar con la tarea inmensa de tasar toda la ciudad. Al principio, estaban prácticamente solos y avanzaban con lentitud. Les llevó tres años diseñar los precios básicos en 56 barrios para asignar un precio único para toda la zona.

La iniciativa coincidió con la incursión del Instituto Lincoln en China de ese mismo año, cuando comenzó a desarrollar relaciones con organismos gubernamentales y organizar proyectos de investigación sobre temas que variaban entre impuesto a la propiedad y financiación municipal de gestión pública de suelo, y expropiación territorial. McCarthy dijo: “Notamos los cambios a medida que se abría la economía, y pensamos que habría que luchar con todo tipo de desafíos en políticas de suelo”.

En 2007, el Instituto Lincoln y la Universidad de Pekín, la más antigua y prestigiosa del país, se esforzaron por abrir el PLC, un instituto de investigación con empleados de ambas organizaciones. Una de sus primeras tareas fue ayudar al gobierno chino a comprender cómo crear un impuesto inmobiliario que funcionara como sistema de renta pública. El PLC organizó eventos de capacitación para difundir en China los conocimientos internacionales sobre tributos inmobiliarios y valuación masiva asistida por computadora. Invitó a expertos de la Asociación Internacional de Peritos Valuadores, el International Property Tax Institute (IPTI, Instituto internacional de tributos inmobiliarios), el Departamento de Clasificación y Tasación de Hong Kong, ESRI Canadá y otros. Para demostrar mejor el funcionamiento de CAMA, el PLC lanzó un proyecto piloto demostrativo que estableció un sistema de CAMA para el distrito financiero de Beijing. También movilizó a expertos internacionales hacia Shenzhen y Hangzhou, y financió recorridos de estudio para el personal técnico en Estados Unidos, Canadá y Hong Kong. El impacto fue inmenso.

“El PLC traducía la bibliografía profesional sobre la tasación de propiedades, y algunas de esas cosas eran nuevas para nosotros”, cuenta el Dr. Wang Youjie, director del departamento de Valuaciones masivas del centro de Shenzhen. “También nos presentaron a CAMA”.

Dado que pudieron acceder a una gran cantidad de conocimientos desarrollados, se aceleró el progreso en la ciudad. Hacia 2010, el centro había evaluado los precios individuales de unos 170.000 edificios, y en 2011, había hecho evaluaciones básicas en 1,5 millones de propiedades residenciales. “El período de 2010 a 2011, una vez que comprendimos mejor la teoría, fue un punto de inflexión para nosotros”, dice Xia Lei, directora del Centro de tasaciones de Shenzhen.

También fue importante el papel del Instituto Lincoln como vínculo, ya que consiguió que los mejores expertos extranjeros ofrecieran seminarios, capacitaciones prácticas y trabajos de desarrollo. A la fecha, el Instituto Lincoln ha llevado a China más de 20 expertos en impuestos inmobiliarios. Para el centro de tasaciones de Shenzhen, el más conocido fue Michael Lomax.

Lomax trabajó durante 22 años como asesor inmobiliario para British Columbia Assessment, un organismo provincial de tasación de Canadá. Fue uno de los primeros que el Instituto Lincoln llevó a China, en 2007, cuando se unió a una delegación gubernamental. Siguió haciendo viajes a China incluso luego de abandonar British Columbia Assessment, en 2012, para trabajar con ESRO, que se especializa en soluciones SIG.

“Gran parte de mi trabajo en China fue demostrar, transmitir y ayudar a instalar las mejores prácticas del mundo”, dice Lomax, que también enseña valuación masiva en la Universidad de Columbia Británica. Alrededor de 2011 empezó a trabajar más directamente con el centro de Shenzhen, y una empresa de tasaciones lo contrató para la ciudad de Hangzhou, Zhejiang, no muy lejos de Shanghái. Al igual que Shenzhen, Hangzhou es conocida por la industria tecnológica e incluye la sede de Alibaba, el titán del comercio electrónico.

En algunos momentos, la rapidez con la que trabajaban ambas ciudades resultaba impresionante. En uno de sus viajes a Hangzhou, Lomax dedicó un día entero a criticar el sistema de tasaciones armado por el departamento local. A la mañana siguiente, le pidieron que volviera a observarlo. “Sus programadores estuvieron despiertos toda la noche en el hotel para arreglar todos los problemas que había señalado”, dice Lomax, que aún no sale de su asombro. “En occidente esto puede llevar unos seis meses, y ellos lo hicieron en horas”.

El equipo de Shenzhen era igual de impresionante. Según Lomax, llevaron los métodos de evaluación informatizados al siguiente nivel. “Están muy avanzados en lo que es el ajuste de las matemáticas”, destaca. “Shenzhen es mucho mejor que Columbia Británica a la hora de evaluar propiedades de forma dinámica, al paso.

En otras palabras, en Shenzhen había una oportunidad evidente para avanzar con la evolución de GAMA. Wang dice: “Michael fue el que nos dio la idea de introducir GAMA”.

De seguidor a líder

ESRI es una empresa consultora global que se especializa en soluciones SIG y está ayudando a construir modelos GAMA en varios municipios. Están Vancouver, donde trabaja Lomax, el condado de Maricopa, Arizona, donde se encuentra Phoenix, y también Shenzhen. Estos proyectos están en distintas etapas de desarrollo, pero, aun así, el sistema de Shenzhen es impresionante. Ingresar a una demostración del sistema es como habitar en un cuadro dentro de un cuadro, como si uno pudiera mirar dentro de una casa por una ventana y encontrar un “yo virtual”. Pero lo que puede hacer con las tasaciones es todavía más impresionante.

Por supuesto, considera todos los indicadores de un sistema de CAMA tradicional: ubicación, cantidad de habitaciones, metros cuadrados, precios recientes de mercado, etc. También puede estimar el valor de tener cerca una estación de subte o una escuela. La naturaleza tridimensional del sistema exacerba la funcionalidad. Mediante el uso de vectores es posible modelar las ventanas con vistas privilegiadas de todas las unidades de un edificio. Desde el escritorio, el tasador puede determinar si un residente posee una vista panorámica del hermoso parque Lianhuashan, en el centro de Shenzhen (similar a Central Park, pero con palmeras y banianos), o solo la fachada aburrida de un alto edificio vecino. Además, el sistema puede trazar un sol virtual en el cielo y estimar la cantidad de luz solar que recibe un departamento. Además de modelar la luz, también puede modelar sonido , por ejemplo, una unidad en una planta baja frente a una intersección con mucho tráfico está en desventaja en comparación con otra que da a un patio tranquilo.

El sistema considera todos esos factores y sintetiza la tasación final de la propiedad. En total, estos factores pueden llegar a representar una diferencia de valor del 20% entre dos unidades del mismo edificio.

El sistema también se está utilizando para ejecutar mejor los impuestos sobre transacciones de propiedades. En esta prueba más pequeña se evidencia la eficacia de la herramienta: de las millones de propiedades tasadas hasta el momento, solo se realizaron 27.106 apelaciones hasta enero de este año y se tuvieron que recalibrar apenas 282 tasaciones.

El proyecto de tasación de Shenzhen no carece de desafíos. En primera instancia, el mercado es joven, por lo que hay una escasez relativa de datos transaccionales. Además, a veces las transacciones se informan con precios bajos artificiales para evadir impuestos. Por último, el mercado inmobiliario es muy heterogéneo y posee grupos bastante diferentes de tipos de viviendas.

Al momento de implementar un sistema como este, uno de los desafíos más grandes debe ser la cantidad limitada de datos sobre transacciones inmobiliarias. En este sentido, Shenzhen posee una ventaja importante sobre casi cualquier otra ciudad del mundo, en lo que respecta al conocimiento sobre sus propiedades. Todo está recién construido, en particular en el centro de la ciudad, donde el impecable modelo 3D es más impresionante. Esto quiere decir que la información sobre los planos de todos los edificios y pisos existe, está completa y se creó en formatos digitales relativamente fáciles de adaptar al modelo.

El equipo de Shenzhen realizó innovaciones ingeniosas sobre esto con un sistema que llaman enfoque “holístico”. En pocas palabras, primero considera a estos grupos distintos de viviendas como “submercados” separados. Luego establece relaciones entre los submercados y así, pueden estimar los precios en todo el mercado con menos puntos de referencia totales.

El sistema en sí es maravilloso desde el punto de vista técnico, pero también es evidencia de lo avanzada que es la ciudad en conjunto. En muchos sentidos, en un logro que puede darse “solo en Shenzhen”.

Shenzhen también es única en su propio país. Apareció gracias a la mera voluntad política que dio a luz a las Zonas Económicas Especiales y no está bajo la administración directa del gobierno central. Sin embargo, como municipio con nivel de prefectura, disfruta el beneficio de contar con una relación más cercana con el gobierno central que otros municipios de su mismo nivel. El gobierno central otorga más libertades a Shenzhen al momento de probar cosas nuevas.

“En Shenzhen, los organismos gubernamentales como las comisiones municipales de planificación y suelo, o finanzas y tributación cooperan entre sí y se comparten datos”, explica la directora Xia. En el país esto es poco común, por lo que resulta difícil no valorar la importancia de que suceda. Geng Jijin, quien dirigió el centro de tasaciones antes de Xia, en el momento más intenso del desarrollo del modelo, tiene un punto de vista más personal: “Lo importante es ser creativos. Aquí todos venimos de distintas partes de China. La única opción es descifrar cómo llevarnos bien”.

Próximos pasos

La tarea de creación del sistema GAMA para Shenzhen aún no termina. Esto se debe, en parte, a que la ciudad creció de forma tan precipitada que gran parte de los edificios de las últimas localidades anexadas tienen poca documentación. Según la directora Xia, una de las mayores prioridades para los próximos pasos es agregar esas propiedades al sistema. Dada la escala de Shenzhen, es probable que lleve algunos años sortear el desafío.

La implementación del impuesto inmobiliario escapa al alcance del Centro de tasaciones. Wang declaró que se trata de un problema de políticas y el centro no se dedica a eso, y agrega: “Si se aplica la política, Shenzhen está lista para hacerlo”.

Nadie sabe cuándo podría ocurrir esto, dado que los impuestos inmobiliarios tienen semejante sensibilidad política en el país. Si bien hubo dos impuestos piloto en Shanghái y la ciudad de Chongqing, en el sudoeste, fueron muy limitados y se efectuaron más que nada como señal de que dichos impuestos están por llegar. Sin embargo, la presión aumenta. Al no haber un impuesto inmobiliario y dado que disminuyó la renta neta de las ventas de suelo de la que dependen los gobiernos, los presupuestos locales están cada vez más comprometidos.

Mientras tanto, el centro de tasaciones ya está ayudando a difundir conocimientos por fuera de sus límites tan especiales. Se enviaron delegaciones de todo el país para observar el sistema, incluso del otro lado del río, en Hong Kong, y de Taiwán.

Por su parte, McCarthy, presidente del Instituto Lincoln, está listo para encargarse de que los conocimientos y la experiencia lleguen a occidente. En lugares como Boston, donde hay polémica desde hace mucho tiempo sobre las construcciones cerca de Boston Common y las sombras que estas podrían causar, sería útil contar con un sistema que modele el sol.

Es posible que la difusión verdadera del nuevo sistema GAMA sea complicada, y no hay forma de saber cuánto tiempo podría llevar. Pero nada habría podido predecir que una aldea pesquera podría convertirse en una metrópolis en apenas tres décadas.

 


 

Tom Nunlist es director editorial de Sinomedia y jefe de redacción de CKGSB Knowledge, en nombre de Cheung Kong Graduate School of Business, de Beijing.

El autor expresa un agradecimiento especial a Carolyn Wang, tasadora masiva del Centro de tasaciones de Shenzhen, quien lo ayudó a gestionar las entrevistas en Shenzhen. Este artículo no se podría haber escrito sin su ayuda experta y su paciencia destacable.

Crédito de la imagen: Shenzhen Assessment Center

 


 

Referencias

Chen, Xiangming, y Tomas de’Medici. 2009. “The ‘Instant City’ Coming of Age: China’s Shenzhen Special Economic Zone in Thirty Years.” Serie inaugural de informes de trabajo, N.º 2, primavera de 2009. Hartford, CT: Centro de estudios urbanos y globales de Trinity College.

The Economist. 2012. “Time for a Property Tax: A Way to Stabilise Both China’s Wild Property Market and Its Weak Local Finances.” 4 de febrero. www.economist.com/node/21546014.

Centro municipal de recursos electrónicos gubernamentales de Shenzhen. 2017. “Shenzhen Government Online”. http://english.sz.gov.cn.

Wang, Da Wei David. 2016. Urban Villages in the New China: Case of Shenzhen. Nueva York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.

Xiao, Cai, Wang Yu y Hu Yuanyuan. 2017. “Overall Govt Debt Risks ‘Under Control.’” China Daily USA, 13 de julio. http://usa.chinadaily.com.cn/epaper/2017-07/13/content_30102302.htm.